Read this article about the history of capitalism. Although the term capitalism was coined in the 19th century, its practices are much older.
Christian Morale and Medieval Expansion of Capitalism
"It is
easier for a camel to pass through the eye of a needle than for someone
who is rich to enter the kingdom of God," quotes the Gospel of Mark
(10:25). Through sermons, visual imagery, and scriptures, the moral
doctrine of the Christian Church shaped the views of the educated as
well as the mentalities of the broad population in medieval Europe. It
is true that this doctrine could concede to the useful role of merchants
and the ethical value of work and property. It could also be
interpreted very flexibly. However, in this doctrine the love of money
is seen as a root of evil, and the conviction was predominant that the
gains of one person would always imply losses by others. Within this
worldview there was much distrust of great wealth and the practices of
merchants, which after all included credit taking, profit seeking, and
competition. In the name of brotherly altruism and virtuous
selflessness, Christian morals have distrusted the resolute orientation
toward self-interest and have opposed certain capitalist practices,
particularly money lending for interest. This was seen and forbidden as
usury, at least if practiced vis-à-vis "thy brother," that is, members
of someone's own group or religion, not necessarily vis-à-vis strangers
or others (Deuteronomy 23:20).3
Certainly, this doctrine has been
circumvented in many practical ways, and in many ways the Church has
positively contributed to the rise of markets and capitalist practices.
Nevertheless, well into the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries, a
disposition that was either skeptical of or hostile toward capitalism
was dominant in Europe's theologies, philosophies, and theories of
society. This skepticism was amplified by the Republican humanism of the
Renaissance, with its reliance on the rediscovered Aristotle, and his
claim to defend public virtues and values against particularized
self-interest, private wealth, and corruption.
The widespread
distrust, moral rejection, and intellectual criticism, however, neither
prevented nor perceptibly hindered the rise of capitalism in medieval
Europe. Similar to other parts of the world such as Arabia, China, and
South Asia - although a little later than there - merchant capitalism
asserted itself in Europe. Long-distance trade was the leading sector,
across the seas and over land in Asia. Merchants used kin-based,
origin-based, ethnic and cultural ties in order to build trust, protect
themselves against robbery and aggression, or to solve economic problems
through non-economic means. Most of them were pious Christians. They
must have shared the religiously founded reservations against profit
seeking and accumulated wealth. Merchants accommodated to such
prevailing attitudes, to some extent, by adopting a lifestyle and
imagery compatible with religion, by donating heavily to charity, by
creating foundations, and often also by making a "final penance" in old
age through large transfers of wealth to monasteries and churches.
At
the same time they behaved as capitalists do, though within a basically
non-capitalist environment. They were ready to accept high risks, they
granted and received credit, they invested and competed with one
another, and they strove for profit and accumulated wealth. Particularly
when combining trading with banking, they could become very rich and
influential. They used different legal forms for their projects and
enterprises, both in the Roman Law and in the Common Law tradition. They
invented new methods of transmitting, crediting, paying, and computing
such as double bookkeeping "alla Veneziana". Most projects and
enterprises were limited in size and short lived, but some were already
multi-branch and multi-local enterprises, which sometimes survived the
lifespan of their founders and were transferred to heirs and others.
Merchants and bankers, frequently merchant bankers, were at the core of
this very dynamic system.4
Compared with other parts of the
world, especially China, merchant capitalism in medieval Europe had two
characteristics that deserve to be emphasized. On the one hand, merchant
capital, at some points and still to a very limited extent, transcended
the sphere of distribution and penetrated the sphere of production.
This happened both in mining, with its huge capital requirements and
often quite extensive plant operations based on wage labor, and it
happened in the cottage industries. Here and there, merchants began to
exercise influence over artisans and cottage workers - that is, over the
producers of goods they intended to market - by advancing raw materials
to producers, placing orders, and sometimes also providing tools. We
find numerous examples of this in the history of the wool trade in
northern Italy, Flanders, and Brabant, starting in the thirteenth
century at the latest; an early form of what was later termed
proto-industrialization.
On the other hand, there were moves
toward early forms of finance capitalism. From the outset, banking
transactions contained elements of speculation. They were settled, to
the extent that they arose, by merchants along the way. Specialization
in financial business started, and banks began to emerge in North
Italian cities after the twelfth century. There were already 80 banks in
Florence in 1350, some of them with several branches in a number of
European countries. They used the money deposited with them for
financing businesses of different types. In addition, they issued bonds
to city governments, landed and manorial estates, and eventually also to
the highest-ranking spiritual and worldly rulers of Europe, who were in
constant need of money and found it difficult to wage their wars,
fulfill their ceremonial obligations, and promote their territories'
expansion. State formation and the origins of financial capitalism were
closely connected, and this nexus enabled prosperous urban citizens, a
small elite, to establish their influence on politics while
simultaneously making their entrepreneurial success dependent on
powerful rulers and their shifting political fortunes. This pattern
continued in the following centuries.
It seems that European
capitalism was not the first, but had already become particularly
vigorous before 1500. Its dynamics were linked to - and conditioned by -
the peculiar dynamics of Europe's political structure, which was
defined by the plurality of competing and sometimes fighting political
units, in contrast for example to China and its comprehensive empire.
This pluralistic political structure offered European capitalists
particular incentives, opportunities, and influence.5