Capitalism and Its Critics: A Long-Term View
Site: | Saylor Academy |
Course: | HIST363: Global Perspectives on Industrialization |
Book: | Capitalism and Its Critics: A Long-Term View |
Printed by: | Guest user |
Date: | Wednesday, May 14, 2025, 5:40 PM |
Description
Read this article about the history of capitalism. Although the term capitalism was coined in the 19th century, its practices are much older.
The Concept
The concept "capitalism" is much younger than the historical reality it denotes. While "capital" and "capitalist" are older, the noun "capitalism" did not emerge until after the second half of the nineteenth century. The French socialist Louis Blanc used it in 1850, and defined it critically as "appropriation of capital by some, to the exclusion of others". In 1872, the German socialist Wilhelm Liebknecht railed against capitalism as a "juggernaut on the battlefields of industry". And in Britain, the Fabian John A. Hobson, a critic of imperialism, was one of the first to use the concept in the 1890s. However, it did not take long before "capitalism" moved beyond its initially critical and polemical use, becoming a central concept in the social sciences. German authors such as Albert Schäffle, Werner Sombart, Max Weber, and - in a Marxist tradition - Rudolf Hilferding, contributed much to this. Karl Marx had written a great deal about the "capitalist mode of production" and "capitalist accumulation," but he rarely used the noun "capitalism," and if so, somewhat marginally.
Presently the concept is "in," particularly among historians, and particularly in the English-speaking world. In the American Historical Association's state-of-the-field volume American History now, "History of capitalism" stands alongside established subfields such as "women's history" and "cultural history". A recent front-page article in the New York Times carried the headline, "In History Class(es), Capitalism Sees Its Stock Soar". Some authors have started to speak of a "New History of Capitalism" they see emerging. In public debates, capitalism remains controversial. As Sven Beckert recently observed:
During the past few years, few topics have animated the chattering classes more than capitalism. In the wake of the global economic crisis of 2008, questions about the nature, past and viability of capitalism suddenly appeared on evening talk shows and in newspapers throughout the world.1
Source: Jürgen Kocka, https://brill.com/view/book/edcoll/9789004386617/BP000004.xml This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial 4.0 License.
Theme and Definition
The following essay takes seriously that
the concept originated in Europe before moving to other parts of the
world. It takes into consideration that "capitalism" was coined as a
central concept of social criticism as well as of scholarly analysis, a
double function it has maintained, at least with some authors, up to the
present time. It deals with the strange interplay, perhaps dialectics,
between capitalism and critique of capitalism.
Although
"capitalism" only became a broadly used concept after the second half of
the nineteenth century, those who have been using it ever since do not
doubt that it could also be applied to phenomena in periods of the past
before the concept existed. I share this conviction.
In the form
of merchant capitalism, capitalism already existed in the first
millennium of our calendar, for example in Arabia, China, and Europe,
though mostly just in the form of capitalist islands in a sea of
predominantly non-capitalist relationships. In the form of finance
capitalism, capitalism has existed since the high-medieval period in
some parts of Europe; beginning in Northern Italy, and later moving its
center to Antwerp, Amsterdam, and London. In the early modern period,
West and East European agrarian capitalism as well as plantation
capitalism overseas have shaped our image of capitalism as a system of
repressive domination and exploitation, even violence. All of this
happened before industrial capitalism - starting first in England in the
eighteenth century, then in Europe and North America - became the
decisive driving force of capitalist expansion globally. In the present
era of globalization, these different types of capitalism coexist and
interact.
When sketching such a scenario, I presuppose a
definition of capitalism that is narrower than market economy in
general, but broader than industrial capitalism based on wage work en
masse. I want to emphasize decentralization, commodification, and
accumulation as basic characteristics of capitalism. On the one hand, it
is essential that individual and collective actors make use of
(property) rights that enable them to make economic decisions in a
relatively autonomous and decentralized way. On the other hand, markets
serve as the main mechanisms of allocation and coordination;
commodification permeates capitalism in many forms, including the
commodification of labor. Further, capital is central, which means
utilizing resources for investment in the present with the expectation
of higher gains in the future, accepting credit besides using savings
and returns, dealing with uncertainty and risk, and aiming for profit
and accumulation. Change, growth, and expansion are inscribed, however,
in irregular rhythms, with ups and downs, interrupted by crises.2
Christian Morale and Medieval Expansion of Capitalism
"It is
easier for a camel to pass through the eye of a needle than for someone
who is rich to enter the kingdom of God," quotes the Gospel of Mark
(10:25). Through sermons, visual imagery, and scriptures, the moral
doctrine of the Christian Church shaped the views of the educated as
well as the mentalities of the broad population in medieval Europe. It
is true that this doctrine could concede to the useful role of merchants
and the ethical value of work and property. It could also be
interpreted very flexibly. However, in this doctrine the love of money
is seen as a root of evil, and the conviction was predominant that the
gains of one person would always imply losses by others. Within this
worldview there was much distrust of great wealth and the practices of
merchants, which after all included credit taking, profit seeking, and
competition. In the name of brotherly altruism and virtuous
selflessness, Christian morals have distrusted the resolute orientation
toward self-interest and have opposed certain capitalist practices,
particularly money lending for interest. This was seen and forbidden as
usury, at least if practiced vis-à-vis "thy brother," that is, members
of someone's own group or religion, not necessarily vis-à-vis strangers
or others (Deuteronomy 23:20).3
Certainly, this doctrine has been
circumvented in many practical ways, and in many ways the Church has
positively contributed to the rise of markets and capitalist practices.
Nevertheless, well into the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries, a
disposition that was either skeptical of or hostile toward capitalism
was dominant in Europe's theologies, philosophies, and theories of
society. This skepticism was amplified by the Republican humanism of the
Renaissance, with its reliance on the rediscovered Aristotle, and his
claim to defend public virtues and values against particularized
self-interest, private wealth, and corruption.
The widespread
distrust, moral rejection, and intellectual criticism, however, neither
prevented nor perceptibly hindered the rise of capitalism in medieval
Europe. Similar to other parts of the world such as Arabia, China, and
South Asia - although a little later than there - merchant capitalism
asserted itself in Europe. Long-distance trade was the leading sector,
across the seas and over land in Asia. Merchants used kin-based,
origin-based, ethnic and cultural ties in order to build trust, protect
themselves against robbery and aggression, or to solve economic problems
through non-economic means. Most of them were pious Christians. They
must have shared the religiously founded reservations against profit
seeking and accumulated wealth. Merchants accommodated to such
prevailing attitudes, to some extent, by adopting a lifestyle and
imagery compatible with religion, by donating heavily to charity, by
creating foundations, and often also by making a "final penance" in old
age through large transfers of wealth to monasteries and churches.
At
the same time they behaved as capitalists do, though within a basically
non-capitalist environment. They were ready to accept high risks, they
granted and received credit, they invested and competed with one
another, and they strove for profit and accumulated wealth. Particularly
when combining trading with banking, they could become very rich and
influential. They used different legal forms for their projects and
enterprises, both in the Roman Law and in the Common Law tradition. They
invented new methods of transmitting, crediting, paying, and computing
such as double bookkeeping "alla Veneziana". Most projects and
enterprises were limited in size and short lived, but some were already
multi-branch and multi-local enterprises, which sometimes survived the
lifespan of their founders and were transferred to heirs and others.
Merchants and bankers, frequently merchant bankers, were at the core of
this very dynamic system.4
Compared with other parts of the
world, especially China, merchant capitalism in medieval Europe had two
characteristics that deserve to be emphasized. On the one hand, merchant
capital, at some points and still to a very limited extent, transcended
the sphere of distribution and penetrated the sphere of production.
This happened both in mining, with its huge capital requirements and
often quite extensive plant operations based on wage labor, and it
happened in the cottage industries. Here and there, merchants began to
exercise influence over artisans and cottage workers - that is, over the
producers of goods they intended to market - by advancing raw materials
to producers, placing orders, and sometimes also providing tools. We
find numerous examples of this in the history of the wool trade in
northern Italy, Flanders, and Brabant, starting in the thirteenth
century at the latest; an early form of what was later termed
proto-industrialization.
On the other hand, there were moves
toward early forms of finance capitalism. From the outset, banking
transactions contained elements of speculation. They were settled, to
the extent that they arose, by merchants along the way. Specialization
in financial business started, and banks began to emerge in North
Italian cities after the twelfth century. There were already 80 banks in
Florence in 1350, some of them with several branches in a number of
European countries. They used the money deposited with them for
financing businesses of different types. In addition, they issued bonds
to city governments, landed and manorial estates, and eventually also to
the highest-ranking spiritual and worldly rulers of Europe, who were in
constant need of money and found it difficult to wage their wars,
fulfill their ceremonial obligations, and promote their territories'
expansion. State formation and the origins of financial capitalism were
closely connected, and this nexus enabled prosperous urban citizens, a
small elite, to establish their influence on politics while
simultaneously making their entrepreneurial success dependent on
powerful rulers and their shifting political fortunes. This pattern
continued in the following centuries.
It seems that European
capitalism was not the first, but had already become particularly
vigorous before 1500. Its dynamics were linked to - and conditioned by -
the peculiar dynamics of Europe's political structure, which was
defined by the plurality of competing and sometimes fighting political
units, in contrast for example to China and its comprehensive empire.
This pluralistic political structure offered European capitalists
particular incentives, opportunities, and influence.5
Business, Violence and Enlightenment: Capitalist Expansion in the Early Modern Period
The
European expansion into the rest of the world since the fifteenth
century had many motives and driving forces, but the resources,
ambitions, greed, and enterprising spirit of West European commercial
and finance capitalists were, no doubt, among them. From the sixteenth
to the eighteenth century, capitalism developed a new pattern: In
overseas trade, in the colonies, and connected with this, in the
economic life of Europe. A new symbiosis between business and violence
characterized capitalism during those centuries, particularly outside
Europe - but under the influence of Europeans - as became evident in the
many wars and raids, but also in the plantation system on the basis of
unfree labor. Certainly, slavery was not a capitalist invention, but the
capitalist plantation economy in Brazil, the Caribbean, and the
southern regions of North America triggered a huge expansion of the
slave trade and slavery. According to Marx, modern capitalism came into
the world soaked in blood and filth, as a result of violence and
suppression. This is only a half-truth historically, but none the less a
correct observation when one considers the connection between the rise
of capitalism and colonization. This connection is currently intensively
researched.6
Within Europe, capitalism continued its expansion
into the world of production, which was accordingly reshaped. Think of
the different types of agrarian capitalism in Western and Eastern
Europe, think of mining and metal-producing industries, and think of the
proto-industrial reorganization of cottage industry in most industrial
regions of Europe. Productivity growth was one major consequence that
decisively improved the life chances - and frequently the survival
chances - of a rapidly growing population. However, new forms of
inequality, dependence, and exploitation also followed, which could not
be realized without some violence and many social conflicts.
The
combination of merchant and finance capitalism with colonialism
triggered innovations. The enterprise, a core element of capitalism in
its process of consolidation, became more clearly profiled by gaining
elements of a legal and institutional identity beyond the people who
founded and managed it. The Dutch Vereenigde Oostindische Compagnie (the
VOC, founded in 1602) was just one, but a famous example among several
firms founded for the purpose of colonial trade in a number of
countries, especially in the Netherlands, England, and France. An
impressive capital fund (6.5 million guilders) on the basis of shares,
more than 200 shareholders with limited liability, power with a board of
directors, sophisticated organization with a transnational and
transregional reach, a central office in Amsterdam soon with about 350
employees, a diversified portfolio of trading activities including some
production units, for example a spinning mill in India: A very modern
corporation, indeed. However, it rested on the foundations of political
privilege and was a monopoly with extensive quasi-governmental powers.
The Dutch government had conferred on the VOC the right to operate all
Dutch trading business east of the Cape of Good Hope, along with the
authorization to wage war, conclude treaties, take possession of land,
and build fortresses. The VOC executed these rights, often in armed
struggle with competitors from other countries. The distinction between
conducting capitalist business and waging war was fluid. There were
years in which the company apparently drew the major share of its income
from the seizure of competing or enemy ships.
The VOC held
together until 1799, while its shareholders continuously changed. They
could easily enter and leave the corporation because they could sell and
buy their shares on newly emerging stock markets; in Antwerp from 1460,
in Amsterdam from 1612, and in London from 1698, with a precursor from
1571. The shares of the monopoly companies engaged in colonial business
represented a considerable proportion of the commercial papers traded on
the stock exchanges. Capital increasingly became a commodity, and the
speculative elements associated with it grew by leaps and bounds. Not
only did the prospect of spectacular profits increase as a result, but
also the danger of great losses. Both the opportunities and the perils
soon affected not just a small number of active, professional trade
capitalists, but also an increasing number of small and large investors
from wide sections of the population in western European metropolises.
In the course of the seventeenth century they learned how to try their
luck on the stock exchange, to bet, to invest, and to speculate, with
prospects and dangers. The downfall of the English South Sea Company in
1720 was preceded by fully-fledged speculation mania. The British
government had granted the company a monopoly on trade with South
America, even including all the rights to regions not yet discovered!
The public expected huge gains. A run on shares set in, and the share
price rose from 100 to 905 pounds within just one month. Broad segments
of the population entrusted their money to the company and lost it when
the bubble burst in the summer of 1720, and the share price went into
free fall. Sir Isaac Newton was among the victims. He is supposed to
have said: "I can calculate the motions of erratic stars, but not the
madness of the multitude". The macro-economic and social consequences of
such crises still remained quite limited. Yet, via stock market and
speculation, larger segments of society got their first introduction to
the hopes and disappointments, the gains and the losses that capitalism
so abundantly held in store for them.
The rise of finance
capitalism not only followed from the growing credit needs of trade and
production through expansion. Rather, the services provided by banks
were also requested by those in power; by city governments and ruling
aristocrats, and later on above all, by the governments of the powerful
territorial states just establishing themselves by competing and
sometimes by fighting with one another. Step by step, the center of
transnational finance capitalism moved to Western Europe, first to
Antwerp and Amsterdam, then later to London.7
In the Netherlands
and in England particularly, capitalist principles affected social life
beyond the economy, sociability, consumption, leisure activities,
betting and sports, the relation between the sexes, and the distribution
of political power. In the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries, the
Netherlands and England were the most capitalist countries in Europe
and, for that matter, the world. It is worthwhile to note that they were
also the most prosperous countries and certainly also the freest in
Europe, on the way to constitutional government and a dynamic civil
society.
I have discussed the skepticism about trade and
capitalism, and the anti-capitalist sentiments dominant in medieval
Europe, under the influence of Christian moral doctrine and other
factors. Certainly, Reformation and Counter-Reformation brought about a
"modern religiosity" that stressed the "worldliness of faith"8 and
contributed to an upgraded appreciation of work and profession. Max
Weber has emphasized this, not without some justification.
Nevertheless,
it was not so much the Reformation, but instead the Enlightenment that
brought about a re-assessment in contemporary thinking about capitalism
and its reputation, at least among intellectuals and probably beyond.
Under the impact of their era's destructive wars, authors such as
Grotius, Hobbes, Locke, and Spinoza worked at redefining the virtues of
civil society with a secularizing thrust and informed by a concern about
human rights, freedom, peace, and prosperity. In 1748, in a clear
withdrawal from the old European mainstream, Montesquieu praised trade
as a civilizing force that contributed to overcoming barbarism, calming
aggression, and refining manners. Other authors chimed in to the same
tune, among them Bernard de Mandeville and David Hume, Condorcet, and of
course Adam Smith; all of them West European thinkers. The common good,
went the thrust of these arguments, is actually promoted by the
reasonable pursuit of self-interest; the advantage of the one need not
be to the disadvantage of the other. Commerce and morality were not
locked into inevitable opposition. The market helped replace the war of
passions with the advocacy of interests. Commerce was said to promote
such virtues as diligence and persistence, uprightness, and discipline.
Overall,
a fundamental affirmation of society's new capitalist tendencies was
starting to emerge. It was expected not only that these tendencies would
increase prosperity, but also that they would contribute to creating a
new social order that was better for human cooperation, one without
arbitrary state intervention, with respect for liberty and individual
responsibility, and with the capacity for resolving conflicts through
compromise instead of war. Certainly, these authors did not use the
concept "capitalism". Adam Smith wrote about "commercial society".
However, basically this was a legitimizing vision of capitalism as a
civilizing promise in the spirit of Enlightenment.
With regard to
appreciation by intellectuals and to public opinion, capitalism had its
best time in the second half of the eighteenth century. However, again
there was a wide gap between reality and discourse; now between the deep
contradictions of capitalist reality and its utopian idealization in
terms of "doux commerce" and "commercial society".9
Industrial Capitalism and Classical Critique in the Long Nineteenth Century
I
am jumping forward by one century. In Werner Sombart's and Max Weber's
analysis of capitalism, for example, there was much confidence in the
economic superiority and the economic rationality of capitalism.
However, these authors did not see capitalism anymore as a carrier of
human progress, moral improvement, and civilizational uplift. On the
contrary, liberals like Weber feared the increasing rigidity of the
system that he anticipated would threaten human freedom by coercing
economic actors to function according to its increasingly compulsive
rules of relentless competition and growth, or to drop out of the market
altogether. Among conservatives as well as on the left, capitalism was
seen as an irresistible force of erosion: Custom was seen to be replaced
by contract, Gemeinschaft by Gesellschaft, the traditional by the
modern, and social bonds by the market. On the right, anti-capitalism
frequently went hand in hand with anti-liberalism and anti-Semitism,
particularly after the Great Depression of the 1870s. The socialist
critique of capitalism was different, and the most powerful one. On the
one hand, it attacked the exploitation of labor by capital, the increase
of social inequality, the lack of a fair deal, and alienation and
suppression in the workplace. On the other hand, it predicted the
decline of capitalism due to its internal contradictions and its
replacement by something new; namely socialism. Many of those who did
not enjoy this perspective did not contest it either, but were fearful
of its arrival.
The discourse of ascent and flourishing had
largely been replaced by a discourse of fall and decline. I mentioned at
the beginning that this was the intellectual, mental situation in which
the concept of capitalism emerged, first as a critical and polemical
concept; soon to be turned into a powerful analytical tool. The concept
emerged, one might say, as a concept of difference. It was used to
identify and critically underline certain features of the present, in
contrast to what it was thought to have been in previous times, and to
what it might become under socialism in the future. The contrast with a
selectively commemorated past and with an imagined future was
constitutive for the emergence of the concept "capitalism," and in a way
this mechanism still works today when it comes to more basic
discussions of capitalism.10
How can we explain this change in
the evaluation of capitalism between the late eighteenth, late
nineteenth, and early twentieth century; this change of mood from
appreciation to criticism? Let me pick out three relevant issues.
1.
While Adam Smith had known capitalism before industrialization,
nineteenth-century capitalism mainly spread in the form of industrial
capitalism, based on the factory system and wage labor en masse. Now the
capitalist principle of commodification was fully extended into the
sphere of work and labor, to the activities of human beings on a grand
scale. Work relations were becoming capitalist, which meant that they
became dependent on changing market mechanisms, subject to ever stricter
calculation, and subordinated to supervision by employers or managers.
At the same time, industrial wealth was accumulated to an unprecedented
degree, due to an increasing need for large-scale fixed capital in
mines, factories, railways, and other institutions of industrial
capitalism. As a consequence, wealth differences became more visible,
and stricter controls of profitability over time were felt to be needed
and were practiced by employers and managers. The class difference had
been built into capitalism as a potentiality from the start; now it
became more manifest. It could be directly experienced, widely observed,
and critically discussed. This was the constellation - industrial
capitalism with the factory system, large-scale capital accumulation,
and wage labor as a mass phenomenon - which served as the empirical base
for the classic narratives of Marx and Engels, and for the rise of
labor movements critical of or hostile to (basic elements of)
capitalism.11
2. Technological and organizational innovation
became much more important, frequent, and regular under industrial
capitalism than ever before. In other words, what Joseph A. Schumpeter
would later call "creative destruction" became the rule and a widespread
experience. Factories pushed aside cottage work in the spinning of yarn
and the weaving of clothes. Steamships replaced traditional forms of
transportation on rivers, canals, and oceans. Producers of electrical
installations gained superiority over the providers of gas-powered
lighting. This was a process opening up new opportunities to many and
new roads towards success, but there were also numerous losers at the
same time. Ascent and decline are mechanisms anchored right at the core
of capitalism. Permanent competition, sustained insecurity, and
threatening dangers were institutionalized; and resented. There were
many losers. All of this came in cycles, with ups and downs, booms and
busts. Nineteenth-century crises impacted on large segments of the
populations. The crises helped to delegitimize capitalism and increase
anti-capitalist resentment.12
3. There was a rise of
expectations. Partly as a precondition and partly as a consequence of
capitalist industrialization, previous patterns of social control were
loosened, the standard of living was raised, fast historical change was
experienced, and human affairs appeared - in fact proved - to be
changeable. The level of education was raised, and public spaces emerged
in which intellectuals and the media played a dynamic, frequently a
critical, role. As a consequence, people became less patient, more
demanding, and more critical. In a way, capitalism's critique followed
from capitalism's success; something analyzed by Joseph Schumpeter and
Albert Hirschman as capitalism's propensity to undermine itself.
All
of this had surfaced by the end of the nineteenth and the start of the
twentieth century, very much in contrast to the period of Adam Smith.
While capitalism developed its strengths and powerfully expanded - both
internally (into different spheres of life) and externally (towards
different parts of the world) - its image darkened, its evaluation
became increasingly pessimistic, and its past and its present were
heavily criticized.
The Present Situation
Since then another century has passed,
which has brought deep changes different from what Max Weber and his
contemporaries had expected. There have been far-reaching technical and
organizational innovations, the digital revolution of recent decades
among them. There has been an unprecedented expansion and
differentiation of consumption, including mass consumption, but also
pronounced socioeconomic inequality which, within our societies, has
started to grow again since the 1970s. In this "century of extremes"
(Eric J. Hobsbawm), people in Europe and elsewhere have experienced
unprecedented social, political, and cultural upheaval, somehow related
to capitalism, largely initiated by Europeans, but impacting on most
other parts of the world as well, among them the deep crisis of
capitalism in the interwar period facilitating the rise of fascism and
World War II.
We have experienced the rise of a powerful,
anti-capitalist alternative: The Soviet type of state socialism, which
radicalized the rejection of capitalism in a very practical and
effective way for decades, before it lost out in a worldwide conflict
and imploded.
Particularly in Europe, coordinated, organized,
regulated forms of capitalism were invented and made concrete with the
help of organized interest groups, including organized labor, and with
the welfare state as its centerpiece. The beginnings of "organized
capitalism" - others prefer to speak of "coordinated capitalism" or the
"Keynesian welfare state" - can be traced back to the late nineteenth
century and World War I, but it really flourished in the third quarter
of the twentieth century, when it proved to be very compatible with
representative democracy. However, it has been questioned (though not at
all destroyed) under the more market-radical, "neo-liberal" auspices in
more recent decades, which have been characterized by an unproportional
rise of finance capitalism and financialization.
In the latter
part of the twentieth and the early twenty-first century, globalization -
understood as increasing interdependence, not as increasing convergence
- proceeded with accelerated speed, across borders between countries
and world regions; conditioned by and affecting large parts of
capitalism that have become more transnational and global than ever
before. This poses an unresolved problem for any form of regulation and
coordination of capitalism by political means, since political power is
still largely vested in competing national states (the criticism of
capitalism and the criticism of globalization are nowadays intrinsically
mixed). The global dimension of present-day capitalism dramatically
increases its destructive impact on the natural environment including
climate; a problem largely absent in previous centuries.13
As
mentioned in the beginning, more and more authors find the concept
"capitalism" useful, in one way or another. Especially when it comes to
discussing complex connections among economic, social, political, and
cultural dimensions of historical reality, and to synthesizing or making
broad comparisons across space and time, historians and historically
oriented social scientists make use of the concept. On the other hand,
the concept continues to serve as an interpretative concept that invites
fundamental debate about the past, present, and future. It certainly
plays a role in intellectual and political debates outside the scholarly
world, too, as it already had around 1900.
There are authors who
use the concept of capitalism with clearly positive overtones, for
example economists in the tradition of the Chicago School. Take the late
Gary Becker as an example, who wrote: "Capitalism with free markets is
the most effective system yet devised for raising both economic
well-being and political freedom". In popular literature too, the term
"capitalism" is used in an affirmative sense.14 There are also numerous
examples of a primarily analytical, "neutral" use of the concept, such
as in the long and ongoing debate by economists and political scientists
about "varieties of capitalism". In this debate, we usually distinguish
between types of capitalism according to different relationships
between market and state, ranging from a relatively market-radical
model, especially in the U.S., to state-capitalist forms, especially in
East Asia, with different forms of coordinated or organized capitalism
in combination with strong welfare state elements in the middle,
especially on the European continent.15
Anyone who takes a
serious look at the history of capitalism and, moreover, knows something
about life in centuries past that were either not capitalist or were
barely so, cannot but be impressed by the immense progress that has
taken place in large parts of the world (though not everywhere). In
spite of its very unequal distribution, this progress has also impacted
on the broad masses of people who did not and do not belong to the
elites and well-situated upper-strata; with regard to material living
conditions and everyday life, gains in life span and health,
opportunities for choice, and freedom.16 It was progress of which one
might say, in retrospect that it would presumably not have happened
without capitalism's characteristic way of constantly stirring things
up, pushing them forward, and reshaping them. To date, alternatives to
capitalism have proven inferior, both with regard to the creation of
prosperity and to the facilitation of freedom. The downfall of the
centrally administered state-socialist economies in the last third of
the twentieth century was, in this respect, a key process for evaluating
the historical balance sheet of capitalism.
Nevertheless,
particularly in Europe the concept continues most frequently to be used
with skeptical or pessimistic overtones, in a spirit of criticism or at
least of ambivalence, and with much sensitivity for the dark sides of
capitalism's record. There are notable continuities in the criticism of
capitalism. Take the catholic social teaching as an example, with its
critique of the "idolatry of the market" and its rejection of "radical
capitalist ideology" (Centesimo Annus, the papal encyclical of 1991).
The current pope, undoubtedly against the background of his experiences
of countries from the Global South, has again intensified the tone of
the Catholic critique.17 Other examples of discursive continuities can
be found in different currents of (what I want to call) a totalizing
critique that rejects "capitalism" as the epitome of (Western) modernity
or as the outright embodiment of evil. This type of fundamentalism is
hard to discuss.18 Now, as in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries,
criticism of capitalism can be raised from standpoints on the political
left - for example by rejecting inequalities and dependencies coming
with capitalist relations - or from standpoints on the political right -
for example with anti-liberal, anti-cosmopolitan, nativist
implications. Politically, Kapitalismuskritik is polyvalent and
ambiguous.
Some critiques of capitalism that were once at the
center of attention have, however, moved to the margins. This is true
for the classical Marxist critique of capitalism as the site of the
alienation of labor and of the immiseration of the working class. In
most economically developed parts of the world, the "labor question" has
ceased to have the explosive and mobilizing effects it used to display
in the nineteenth and first part of the twentieth century. Nevertheless,
at the global level it deserves to be rediscovered, given the massive
spread of so-called "informal labor" under conditions of capitalist
exploitation in the Global South.19
Other topics have moved to
the foreground. Concrete abuses are denounced, such as "structured
irresponsibility" in the financial sector. That lack of accountability
has led to a widening gap - incidentally, in violation of one of
capitalism's central premises - between deciding, on the one hand, and
answering to the consequences of decisions, on the other. As a result,
exorbitant profits for money managers are facilitated by public budgets
that take on gigantic losses ("too big to fail").20 Moreover, the
contemporary critique of growing inequality as a consequence of
capitalism is becoming ever more urgent. Here, public discussion has
focused on the kind of inequality of income and of wealth distribution
that since the 1970s has become much more severe inside most individual
countries; there has been less interest in the much more serious
inequality that exists between countries and regions of the globe. The
latter grew immensely between 1800 and 1950, but no longer did so after
that. Lamenting the growth of inequality blends into protest against
infringements on distributive justice, which is how the critique becomes
systemically relevant.21 One criticizes the discrepancy between, on the
one hand, the claim of democratic politics to shape our common
destinies according to democratic principles and procedures, and on the
other hand, the dynamic of capitalism that evades democratic politics.
The relationship between capitalism and democracy continues to be a much
discussed theme.22 Also lamented are the perennial insecurity,
unrelenting acceleration pressures, and extreme individualization that
are inherent to capitalism and that may lead, in the absence of
countermeasures, to the erosion of social welfare and neglect of the
public interest. Similar, in the way it poses fundamental questions, is
the critique of capitalism's intrinsic dependence on permanent growth
and constant expansion beyond the attained status quo; a dependence that
threatens to destroy natural resources (the environment and climate)
and cultural resources (solidarity and meaning). These are resources
that capitalism needs in order to survive, but that it increasingly
exhausts and destroys.23 This, in turn, raises the urgent question of
where the limits of the market and of venality lie, or where - on moral
or practical grounds - they should be drawn. The historical overview
offers strong arguments for the case that there is a need for such
boundaries: That capitalism, in other words, cannot be allowed to
permeate everything, but that it needs non-capitalist abutments in
society, culture, and the state.24
Certainly, there are those who
defend capitalism in the public debate. They have good arguments, which
demonstrate its achievements, its alliance with progress, and its
beneficial effects over the centuries. However, by and large the
critical, skeptical, pessimistic arguments, connotations, and overtones
dominate - particularly since the Great Recession of 2008 - both in
public debates and in relevant parts of the social sciences, at least in
Europe. Writings about "postcapitalism" are selling well, nowadays with
frequent references to the impact of digitalization and the inclination
to predict the imminent end of capitalism as we have known it.25 With
changing arguments in detail, this type of literature has a long
tradition.
Conclusion and Coda
At any point in time, very different and even
contradictory assessments of capitalism have coexisted or competed,
which is why it is hard to generalize. If we do nevertheless generalize,
we may conclude that over the centuries in Europe, the rise, the
breakthrough, and finally the triumph of capitalism have taken place in
an intellectual and mental climate of pronounced Kapitalismuskritik, or
criticism of capitalism. If this conclusion is correct, one may wonder
why these skeptical and critical sentiments and convictions have not
hindered or handicapped the real rise of European or European-sponsored
capitalism more than is apparently the case. An achievement with a bad
conscience? A typical contradiction between basis and superstructure? A
century-old hypocrisy not unknown in the history of public morale and
noble principles? A European Sonderweg?
One can offer a more
constructive hypothesis and hold that the widespread criticism of
capitalism has contributed to its permanent change and reform - as well
as indirectly and inadvertently to its survival and success - over the
centuries. One could show in detail that ideas and discourses of
Kapitalismuskritik, once they managed to be translated into social and
political energy, have led to reforms that improved and civilized
capitalism, making it more compatible with human needs. This has
enhanced its social acceptance and ultimately its capability to survive.
It is neither guaranteed nor excluded that this mechanism will continue
to work in the future.
Sometimes the difficult and ambivalent
concept "capitalism" reminds me of the similarly difficult and
ambivalent concept "modernity".26 Both concepts relate to an impressive
multitude of very different empirical phenomena, with respect to which
one sometimes wonders why they should be assembled under one and the
same conceptual roof. Both are rather abstract constructs, which were
originally created by relating them to basic value judgements. Both
share particular temporal structures in that they try to make present
phenomena intelligible by differentiating them from past and future
phenomena; from objects of remembrance on the one hand, and from objects
of imagination on the other. In one case (modernity), hope and the
expectation of progress stimulated the conceptual construction, in the
other case (capitalism), it was criticism. In both cases, concepts
emerged from acts of evaluation, but this did not prevent them from
becoming instruments of sophisticated analysis.
The comparison
with the concept "modernity" highlights the fact that the concept
"capitalism" not only serves the purpose of understanding and
interpreting present realities, but also serves as a conceptual foil on
which very different expectations, anxieties, and hopes can be projected
in order to be articulated, asserted and, if possible, accomplished.
That means that the concept may tend to change the reality that it helps
to represent and understand: The concept as a sort of intervention.
Endnotes
* Earlier versions of this text have been presented as lectures
at the Germany Institute Amsterdam, 27 October 2016 and at the Royal
Flemish Academy of Belgium for Sciences and the Arts (Class of
Humanities) in Brussels, 18 March 2017.
- Sven Beckert, "The New History of Capitalism," in Jürgen Kocka and Marcel van der Linden, eds., Capitalism. The Reemergence of a Historical Concept (London/New York, 2016), 235–249, here 235; Seth Rockman, What Makes the History of Capitalism Newsworthy? Journal of the Early Republic 34, no. 3 (2014): 439–466, esp. 439; Friedrich Lenger, "Die neue Kapitalismusgeschichte. Ein Forschungsbericht als Einleitung," Archiv für Sozialgeschichte 56 (2016): 3–37. Early usages of the concept are documented in: Jürgen Kocka, "Capitalism: The History of the Concept," in International Encyclopedia of the Social & Behavioral Sciences, 2nd ed., ed. James D. Wright, vol. 3 (Amsterdam, 2015), 105–110.
- Overview and definition based on Jürgen Kocka, Capitalism. A Short History (Princeton, N.J., 2016), 7–24; further elaborated by Marcel van der Linden, "Final Thoughts," in Capitalism, eds. Kocka and van der Linden, 251–266, esp. 255–258.
- With many differentiations: Jacques Le Goff, La bourse et la vie: Economie et religion au Moyen Age (Paris, 1986); Martha C. Howell, Commerce before capitalism in Europe, 1300–1600 (London, 2010), 261–297;
- Giacomo Todeschini, "Credit and Debt: Patterns of Exchange in Western Christian Society," in Europas Aufstieg. Eine Spurensuche im späten Mittelalter, ed. Thomas Ertl (Wien, 2013), 139–160.
- Josef Kulischer, Allgemeine Wirtschaftsgeschichte des Mittelalters und der Neuzeit. vol I, 3rd ed. (Munich, 1965), 229–278; M.C. Howell, Commerce Before Capitalism in Europe, 1300–1600 (Cambridge, 2010); K.G. Persson, "Markets and Coercion in Medieval Europe," in The Cambridge History of Capitalism, vol. I, eds. L. Neal and J.G. Williamson (Cambridge, 2014), 225–266; Jacques Le Goff, Marchands et Banquiers au Moyen Age (Paris, 1956); Jacques Le Goff, Le Moyen Age et l'Argent (Paris, 2010); Giacomo Todeschini, "Theological Roots of the Medieval/Modern Merchants' Self-Representation," in The Self-Perception of Early Modern Capitalists, eds. Margaret C. Jacobs and Catherine Secretan (London, 2008), 17–46; Herman Van der Wee and G. Kurgan-van Hentenryk, eds., A History of European Banking, 2nd ed. (Antwerp, 2000), 71–112.
- This essentially older argument (Max Weber, Otto Hintze, Kenneth Pomeranz, Peer Vries) is well developed in: E.H. Mielants, The Origins of Capitalism and the "Rise of the West" (Philadelphia, 2007); in another version in: R. Bin Wong and J.-L. Rosenthal, Before and Beyond Divergence: The Politics of Economic Change in China and Europe (Cambridge, MA, 2011).
- E.g. in: E.E. Baptist, The Half Has Never Been Told: Slavery and the Making of American Capitalism (New York, 2014); Sven Beckert, Empire of Cotton: A Global History (New York, 2014); Sven Beckert and Seth Rockman, eds., Slavery's Capitalism: A New History of American Economic Development (Philadelphia, 2015); Karl Marx, Das Kapital. Kritik der politischen Ökonomie, Marx/Engels Werke, vol. 33 (Berlin, 1962), 788.
- Last paragraphs based on Kocka, Capitalism, 54–83. On European expansion to Asia: Wolfgang Reinhard, Kleine Geschichte des Kolonialismus, 2nd ed. (Stuttgart, 2008), 27–65, esp. 42–47 (VOC); P.A. Frentrop, History of Corporate Governance, 1602–2002 (Amsterdam, 2002), 49–114; Newton quote: Patrick Brantlinger, Fictions of State: Culture and Credit in Britain, 1694–1994 (Ithaca, NY, 1996), 44; C.P. Kindleberger and R. Aliber, Manias, Panics and Crashes: A History of Financial Crises, 5th ed. (Hoboken, NJ, 2005), 42, 58; Van der Wee and Kurgan-Van Hentenryk, eds., History, 117–264, esp. 260; T. Sokoll, Europäischer Bergbau im Übergang zur Neuzeit (Idstein, 1994); P. Kriedte et al., Industrialization before Industrialization: Rural Industry in the Genesis of Capitalism (Cambridge, 1981); Robert Brenner, "The Agrarian Roots of European Capitalism," Past & Present 97 (1982): 16–113.
- Heinz Schilling, Martin Luther. Rebell in einer Zeit des Umbruchs (Munich, 2012), 634.
- Most important: Albert O. Hirschman, Rival Views of Market Society and Other Recent Essays (Cambridge, Mass., 1992), 105–141, esp. 106; very good: Jerry Z. Muller, The Mind and the Market: Capitalism in Western Thought (New York, 2002; paperback 2003), 3–19 (on the older more skeptical perspectives) and 51–83 (on Smith); on changing views in the eighteenth century: J. Appleby, The Relentless Revolution: A History of Capitalism (New York, 2010), 87–120; on changing cultural practices in England: Christiane Eisenberg, The Rise of Market Society in England, 1066–1800 (New York, 2014), 73–100.
- Documentation in Kocka, "Capitalism: The History of the Concept". On the temporal structure of capitalist practices and debates about capitalism: Jens Beckert, Imagined Futures. Fictional Expectations and Capitalist Dynamics (Cambridge, MA, 2016). On Max Weber's notions of capitalism: Max Weber, Economy and Society: An Outline of Interpretive Sociology, eds. Guenther Roth and Claus Wittich (Berkeley, CA, 1978, reprinted 2013), 63–166, 351–54, 1094–110; Max Weber, General Economic History, trans. Frank H. Knight (Glencoe, IL, 1927, reprinted 1950), 275–369; Max Weber, The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism, (1920), revised, trans. and intro. Stephen Kalberg (New York, 2010); Werner Sombart, Der moderne Kapitalismus, 3 vols. 2nd ed. (Munich/Leipzig, 1924–1927).
- With reference to the German case: Jürgen Kocka, Arbeitsverhältnisse und Arbeiterexistenzen: Grundlagen der Klassenbildung im 19. Jahrhundert (Bonn, 1990); Jürgen Kocka, Arbeiterleben und Arbeiterkultur. Die Entstehung einer sozialen Klasse (Bonn, 2015); Marcel van der Linden and J. Rojahn, eds., The Formation of Labour Movements 1870–1914, 2 vols. (Leiden, 1990).
- Joseph A. Schumpeter, Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy, 2nd ed. (New York, 1947), 81–86 ("creative destruction").
- The concept "organized capitalism" goes back to Rudolf Hilferding. See his Das Finanzkapital (Vienna, 1910). The concept was successfully tried out for purposes of historical analysis: Heinrich August Winkler, ed., Organisierter Kapitalismus: Voraussetzungen und Anfänge (Göttingen, 1974). Also see Colin Crouch, Industrial Relations and European State Tradition (Oxford, 1993). Relevant debates in the U.S. are analyzed in: H. Brick, Transcending Capitalism: Visions of a New Society in Modern American Thought (Ithaca, NY, 2006). On the movements away from "organized capitalism" in many Western countries since the 1970s/1980s: Claus Offe, Disorganized Capitalism: Contemporary Transformation of Work and Politics (London, 1985); P. Mirowski and D. Plehwe, eds., The Road from Mont Pèlerin: The Making of the Neoliberal Thought Collective (Cambridge, MA, 2009); G.R. Krippner, Capitalizing on Crisis: The Political Origins of the Rise of Finance (Cambridge, 2011); Ivan T. Berend, An Economic History of Nineteenth-Century Europe (Cambridge, 2013); Jürgen Osterhammel and N.P. Petersson, Globalization: A Short History (Princeton, NJ, 2009). My view on financialization, deregulation, and the changing relations between markets and states in recent decades is presented in Kocka, Capitalism, 114–124, 145–161.
- G.S. Becker and G.N. Becker, The Economics of Life: From Baseball to Affirmative Action to Immigration. How Real-World Issues Affect Our Everyday Life (New York, 1997); J. Mackey, Conscious Capitalism: Liberating the Heroic Spirit of Business (Cambridge, MA, 2013).
- Cf. P.A. Hall and D. Soskice, eds., Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage (Oxford, 2001); B. Amable, The Diversity of Modern Capitalism (Oxford, 2003); R. Dore, Stock Market Capitalism, Welfare Capitalism: Japan and Germany versus the Anglo-Saxons (Oxford, 2000).
- Usefully summarized in J.L. Van Zanden et al., How Was Life? Global Well-Being Since 1820 (Paris, 2014). Along a similar line: Angus Deaton, The Great Escape: Health, Wealth, and the Origins of Inequality (Princeton, 2013).
- Amintori Fanfani, Catholicism, Protestantism, and Capitalism (Norfolk, VA, 2002); Andrea Tornielli and Giacomo Galeazzi, This Economy Kills: Pope Francis on Capitalism and Social Justice (Liturgical Press, 2015).
- Examples can be found in C. Tripp, Islam and the Moral Economy: The Challenge of Capitalism (Cambridge, 2006), though such totalizing condemnations of capitalism are also not unknown in the West.
- Basic: Marcel van der Linden, Workers of the World: Essays Toward a Global Labor History (Leiden, 2008). Cf. J. Breman, Outcast Labour in Asia: Circulation and Informalization of the Workers at the Bottom of the Economy (Oxford, 2012); Andreas Eckert, "Capitalism and Labor in Sub-Saharan Africa," in Capitalism, eds. Kocka and Van der Linden, 165–185.
- C. Honegger et al., eds., Strukturierte Verantwortungslosigkeit: Berichte aus der Bankenwelt (Frankfurt, 2010).
- Cf. A.B. Atkinson, Inequality. What Can be Done? (Cambridge, MA, 2015); Thomas Piketty, Capital in the Twenty-first Century (Cambridge, MA, 2014); Branco Milanovic, Global Inequality. A New Approach for the Age of Globalization (Cambridge, MA, 2016).
- Jürgen Kocka, Capitalism is not Democratic and Democracy not Capitalistic. Tensions and Opportunities in Historical Perspective (Florence, 2015); Jürgen Kocka, "Kapitalismus und Demokratie. Der historische Befund," Archiv für Sozialgeschichte 56 (2016): 39–50: Capitalism has existed and flourished under different political systems. There is scope for political choice and shaping. Much depends on the political orientations and energies a community can mobilize.
- E.g., Naomi Klein, This Changes Everything. Capitalism vs. the Climate (New York, 2014); Jürgen Renn and Bernd Scherer, eds., Das Anthropozän. Zum Stand der Dinge (Berlin, 2015); Michael Mann, "The End May Be Nigh, But for Whom?" in Does Capitalism Have a Future? eds. Immanuel Wallerstein et al. (Oxford, 2013), 71–97. On p. 94 Mann convincingly puts the relationship between capitalism and climate change in a much broader and more complex perspective: "The three great triumphs of the modern period - capitalism, the nation-state, and citizen rights - are responsible for the environmental crisis".
- There is something to be learned from very different authors such as Karl Polányi, The Great Transformation, New York, 1944); Schumpeter, Capitalism; M.J. Sandel, What Money Can't Buy: The Moral Limits of Markets (New York, 2012).
- Wolfgang Streeck, "How will Capitalism End?" New Left Review 87 (2014): 35–64; Jeremy Rifkin, The Zero Marginal Cost Society: The Internet of Things, the Collaborative Commons, and the Eclipse of Capitalism (New York, 2015); Paul Mason, PostCapitalism: A Guide to the Future (London, 2016).
- Cf. Paul Nolte, "Modernization and Modernity in History," in International Encyclopedia of the Social and Behavioral Sciences, vol. 15, eds. Neil J. Smelser and Paul B. Baltes (Oxford, 2001), 9954 ff.; Peter Wagner, Modernity as Experience and Interpretation: A New Sociology of Modernity (London, 2008).
- The Lifework of a Labor Historian: Essays in Honor of Marcel van der Linden