This reference explains one of the causes of financial crises, currency crises, and how fiscal policies play an important role in determining economic outcomes. What are some possible causes of a currency crisis?
To better understand the role of fiscal policy in recent crises in emerging markets, it is important to see how governments in these countries paid for bank and corporate bailouts. Different financing methods have different implications for inflation and depreciation after crises.
The standard fiscal sustainability analysis reflected in equation 2 revolves around a restatement of the government's long-term budget constraint, derived from equation 1:
(3) initial debt = present value of future primary surpluses and seigniorage.
The standard analysis, which works with long-run steady state conditions, is not well suited to thinking about crises. To be useful in understanding the possible effects of a banking crisis, the analysis needs to reflect how governments tend to respond to crises.
For example, standard theory implies that a government in a long-run steady state, with a sustainable fixed exchange rate, could weather a banking crisis without abandoning the exchange rate. It could do so if it could credibly announce its intention and ability to finance any fiscal costs resulting from the cri sis through explicit fiscal reforms – that is, by cutting primary spending or raising taxes. But governments usually do not take such actions, presumably because they are too costly economically or politically.
Thus crisis costs are often financed through other means. Fiscal reforms in the Republic of Korea (starting in 1997) and Mexico (1994) were modest relative to the fiscal costs of banking crises (table 2). Other sources of financing included seigniorage and the depreciation of debt denominated in local currency. Debt sustainability analysis needs to reflect the extent to which governments can and are likely to resort to these sources of financing. It also needs to reflect the fact that crises are often associated with economic downturns that impose additional fiscal costs through lost revenue. This factor was especially important in Korea.
Debt sustainability analysis also needs to show how financing affects economic out comes. Theory suggests that depreciation and inflation after a crisis depend on three factors related to financing. One is the fiscal cost of the crisis net of the value of explicit fiscal reforms. The second is the amount of additional seigniorage revenue the government raises. The third factor is how much revenue the government can raise implicitly - which depends on the degree of exchange rate pass-through to local prices, the amount of the government's nominal debt, and the structure of the government's spending and revenue base.
Burnside, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo (2001a) use the simple monetary models from fiscal sustainability analysis-built around the government budget constraint and a money demand function-to investigate how financing affect<; economic out comes. They use examples in which the exchange rate is initially assumed to be sustainable. By definition this means that the government's fiscal plans are consistent with equation 3, where the amount of seignior age being raised is consistent with maintaining the fixed exchange rate.Indicator | Korea, Rep. of | Mexico |
Fiscal cost of the crisis | 24 | 15 |
New funds raised | 6 | 4.3 |
Seigniorage | 1.1 | 1.5 |
Debt depreciation | 2.9 | 2 |
Fiscal reforms | 7.2 | 1.4 |
Costs of recession | -5.2 | -0.5 |
Yet to be paid for | 18 | 10.7 |
The authors then imagine that the economy is hit by a banking crisis. This increases the left-hand side of equation 3 by the size of the resulting bank bailout. As noted, the government can finance this bailout through a combination of additional seigniorage, explicit fiscal reforms, and implicit fiscal reforms. Implicit reforms occur without direct government action but only if the fixed exchange rate is abandoned. Examples include inflating away the value of local currency debt or other nominal spending commitments, or decreasing the dollar value of public sector wages that might be indexed to the consumer price index and not the exchange rate.
Economic outcomes depend on the mix of financing. Suppose that the government finances the entire fiscal cost of the bank bailout with explicit fiscal reforms. Then a currency crisis can be averted because the government does not need additional seigniorage or implicit revenue-both of which would require it to abandon the fixed exchange rate-to finance its new liabilities. At the opposite extreme, suppose that the government makes no explicit fiscal reform and raises no implicit revenue (that is, the government has no non-indexed local currency debt, fiscal policy is implicitly indexed to foreign currency, and exchange rate pass-through is immediate). Thus it finances the entire bailout with seigniorage. This move would imply a depreciation of the currency matched by an equal increase in inflation.
In Korea neither scenario occurred. There was a currency crisis-implying incomplete explicit fiscal reform-yet inflation was very low-implying that some implicit revenue was raised to finance the cost of bailing out banks, estimated by Standard and Poor's to have been about 24 percent of GDP. Burn side, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo (2001a) con struct an example in which a country facing such a cost pays for about two-thirds of it with explicit fiscal reforms and for one-third in would have been aided, in making their projections, by detailed information on the structure of government debt, spending, and revenue, and by studies of exchange rate pass-through in Korea. This sort of information, in col)junction with the standard tools of fiscal sustainability analysis, would have allowed them to assess the effects of alternative government policies.
roughly equal parts by generating additional seigniorage revenue, inflating away part of its nominal debt, and relying on other implicit fiscal reforms. Together these assumptions on financing, along with modest domestic price stickiness, imply a 60 per cent depreciation of the exchange rate in the first year of the crisis, but only 15 percent inflation. Furthermore, they imply little depreciation or inflation thereafter. These outcomes are similar to those in Korea except for the exchange rate overshooting that occurred there.
The jury is still out on whether Korea will use seigniorage or explicit fiscal reforms to finance the remaining fiscal cost of its banking crisis. Economists performing fiscal sustainability analyses at the time of the crisis would not have been able to fully anticipate the government's future actions. But they