Read this article on the debate surrounding the "Great Divergence". It
takes a critical look at the traditional assumptions on why Europe
seemed to lead the way in industrialization.
Chronology and Protagonists of the Debate on the Great Divergence
Before
looking in more detail at how early modern technology has been
discussed in recent decades in the controversy over the "great
divergence", it might be appropriate to sketch briefly two of the
central features of that debate. This section will survey how the debate
unfolded over time and the academic profiles of its protagonists.
It
is surely not new to compare differences in economic performance of
diverse high cultures in world history. Contemporaries of
industrialization in the nineteenth century already highlighted European
or "Western" superiority as part of colonial and often racist
arguments, for example, in the context of the widely discussed
presentations of material culture on world fairs, starting with the
famous exhibition in London in 1851.
Michael Adas has shown, references to advanced technologies became more and more frequent among the arguments offered by nineteenth-century authors for the cultural dominance of the West9.
In scientific discourse, authors in the early 20th century like the German sociologist Max Weber discussed in detail different developmental paths of various regions of the world and sought cultural explanations for Europe's particular path to industrialization. Much later, in the 1980s and 1990s, a growing awareness of globalization processes led to renewed interest in historical explanations for different developmental paths taken by the various world regions. Since then, the centre of gravity of this debate has shifted away not unlike the swing of a pendulum. The first bestsellers included Eric Jones' The European miracle (1981) and David Landes' The wealth and poverty of nations (1998). Their authors supported the idea of Western dominance by often unduly clear-cut arguments10.
A wealth of studies emerged in the rise of global history
since the 1990s that pointed out the many blind spots in publications
such as those by Jones and Landes. Now, they argued, it was urgently
necessary not just to back the discussion about the "great divergence"
with more solid data from economic history. In particular, the issues at
stake must also be considered on the basis of well-informed research on
Asian. The title of André Gunder Frank's book, Re-Orient (1998),
symbolizes this approach well11. Particularly the "California school",
named as such because its writers taught at Californian universities,
synthesized studies specifically on the economic history of pre-modern
China, to enable a more nuanced comparative analyses.
Despite all
this contention, most of these debaters shared the conviction that
Europe's "special course" into industrialization was to some extent
contingent. British industrialization is not seen as a necessary outcome
of some particular characteristics that had evolved over centuries, but
as a result that emerged somewhat arbitrarily out of a convergence of
factors, among them the availability of coal and ores, the financial
means to invest in large technological projects, and advanced forms of
technical expertise.
Most
recently, this line of research followed by the "California school" is
being supplemented by increasingly specialized studies of non-Western
economic development, providing a more solid basis for comparative
studies12. Some core arguments of the California school have be
questioned, most prominently by the economic historian Peer Vries. He
argues that during the early modern period Britain accumulated a wealth
of factors on the economic level that allowed its transition to
industrialization whereas those possibilities were not available to
China13. At first sight this position seems to mark the pendulum's swing
back to the positions taken by Jones and Landes decades ago, albeit
based on substantial amount of research results and data which became
available since, in particular on Asian economies.
Even if the
debate on the "great divergence" clearly has an interdisciplinary
character, its most visible protagonists are economic historians and
social scientists with a historical interest. It would be hard to over
emphasise that despite the large number of publications that in one way
or another are contributing to the debate, many experts, particularly
those on non-Western cultures, are refraining from engaging in the
debate even if tacitly, although their research experience is highly
relevant to its core issues. There are surely good reasons for this
choice: an inherent problem in the debate on the "great divergence" is
that a presupposition of "Western" categories can hardly be avoided as
its starting point – most prominently, industrialization and economic
growth as the crucial events seeking explanation.
Such Eurocentric
presuppositions have, however, in principle long since been overcome in
the large community of global historians. For many of them global
history, by definition, must not presuppose "Western" categories, but
must devise categories apt for the study of diverse world regions on an
equal level. This position is connected with a more general suspicion
concerning "comparisons" of regions or cultures as such – they have too
often resulted in highlighting what "the West" had and what "the Rest"
did not have. As one of the ways out of this trap, it is usually
proposed to focus instead on concrete interactions and networks,
shifting the attention to processes of exchange and to personalities who
served as brokers between cultures.
As convincing as this
position is, one might also regret its consequences on the debate about
the "great divergence". The puzzling issue "Why Europe?" easily stirs
interest and stimulates discussion in broader audiences of historical
research among the well-informed public. It is thus somewhat deplorable
when historians refrain from explicitly incorporating their positions
into the controversy, even if they may have good reasons for taking a
fundamentally critical stance on this debate as such. Such silence quite
necessarily results in a lopsided assemblage of arguments and a lack of
relevant issues in historical expertise within the debate. As will be
argued in what follows, a related problem also holds true for the factor
of interest here, namely early modern technology.