Technology and Technical Knowledge in the Great Divergence
Site: | Saylor Academy |
Course: | HIST363: Global Perspectives on Industrialization |
Book: | Technology and Technical Knowledge in the Great Divergence |
Printed by: | Guest user |
Date: | Wednesday, May 14, 2025, 5:47 PM |
Description
Read this article on the debate surrounding the "Great Divergence". It
takes a critical look at the traditional assumptions on why Europe
seemed to lead the way in industrialization.
Abstracts
In the search for reasons why industrialization first emerged in Europe and not in other world regions, technology is often referred to as a crucial factor. However, related cross-cultural comparisons still often focus on spectacular inventions and quantifiable performance alone and thus perpetuate Eurocentric categories. The present essay critically discusses this tendency of research. With regard to the issue of technical knowledge, it is proposed to investigate the multitude of aspects of expertise relevant for the realization of technology in any given world region rather than to pursue the traditional focus of the application of "science" to technical problems.
Source: Marcus Popplow, https://journals.openedition.org/artefact/485?lang=en This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 License.
Introduction
Why did industrialization first emerge in Britain and thereupon in other European regions? Why not in other world regions like China, India and the Ottoman Empire? This issue is being debated in the social and historical sciences under the heading "Why Europe1?" Another label as frequently employed for this controversy is the "great divergence", coined by one of its protagonists, Kenneth Pomeranz, historian of China2. The notion "great divergence" conveys the idea that something unprecedented happened in world history towards the end of what historians of Europe call the early modern period. Until then, history on a global scale had repeatedly seen the rise and fall of mighty empires. Periods of "efflorescence" – to use a term suggested by political scientist Jack Goldstone – were followed by economic and cultural decline3. The path into industrialisation taken by some of Europe's core regions and subsequently by the United States is seen in this view as a deviation from such continuous ups and downs, in a development into a hitherto unparalleled continuity of economic growth. The "great divergence" thus highlights the uniqueness of European and Western industrialization, in contrast to the paths taken by all other cultures in world history.
But when
exactly did Europe's "special course4", which is another concept used to
describe this same phenomenon, set in? There is yet no consensus on the
answer to the question, or indeed if asking this question is a
productive way of engaging the past, as will be explained in more detail
later. Apart from the few who advocate its beginnings already during
the European Middle Ages5, most agree, however, that this diverging path
appeared sometime between 1500 and 1800.
Technology as a Crucial Factor for the Great Divergence
In whichever field one seeks the clues for the question "Why Europe?", the reasons must be sought primarily in the early modern period. It is not the aim of this essay to present and discuss all the issues investigated by those involved in discussing this question in different subfield of history focusing on demography or economic institutions, religious beliefs or the availability of natural resources, factors such as the exploitation of colonies in the Americas and others.
Economic
historians, in particular, who are the most active participants in the
debate, have identified a number of core issues, such as wage rates,
agricultural productivity, or anthropometric measures for comparing
standards of living in regions of Europe, China, and India. Their
considerations, based on extensive analysis of the relevant source
material, will not be summarized here either, as recent detailed studies
have presented the respective data6. Within the thematic framework of
the present volume, the aim of this essay is rather to take a closer
look at how "technology" enters and figures in this debate.
When
authors discuss the whole bundle of possible factors that might have
set England, in particular, on its way to industrialization, none can
avoid mentioning technology. In the long run, machines too clearly
appear as indispensable factors for industrialization to be ignored. For
the production of textiles, iron and steel, and many other goods; the
steam engine as a power generator and the motor in locomotives that
accelerated transportation; and the shift to an energy system based on
fossil fuels, later supplemented by electricity as a new form of easily
available energy.
It
would be a gross mistake, however, to identify the factor "technology"
as a special characteristic of Europe or the West in the time period
considered here. It is one of the central lessons of recent research on a
global scale to have provided much detailed information about
technologies used in various world regions in pre-industrial times. The
debate on the "great divergence" and respective cross-cultural
comparisons usually focus predominantly on the seventeenth and
eighteenth centuries. Somewhat implicitly, most authors thus agree that,
towards the end of the European Middle Ages, Eurasian cultures were
disposing over roughly comparable technological equipment and technical
competences.
At that point of time, it is argued, it would thus not have been possible to foresee which of them was better prepared for industrialization: Chinese regions had thriving economies and coal, ores and other resources in abundance. Zheng He had, just some decades earlier, successfully completed his famous exploratory voyages which even led him to the eastern shores of Africa. Asian coastlines were dotted with smaller and larger harbours, which served to exchange a multitude of goods, among them precious wares like silk garments or Chinese porcelain, over large distances to the Arab peninsula – in Europe, too, these luxuries were long being appreciated7.
Textiles were
produced all over Asia in great variety and number, and by refined
techniques. In Arab regions, refined artisanship and complex hydraulic
systems formed the basis of intense commercial networks across Eurasia
as well as far into Africa. It fits into this picture that, up to around
1500, Europe had been an importer of a wide array of technologies and
goods from Asian regions as far as China: examples range from the
compass to gunpowder and complex automata, silk and paper. In early
modern Europe, authors were well aware of these origins and often
mentioned them in their writings8.
Chronology and Protagonists of the Debate on the Great Divergence
Before
looking in more detail at how early modern technology has been
discussed in recent decades in the controversy over the "great
divergence", it might be appropriate to sketch briefly two of the
central features of that debate. This section will survey how the debate
unfolded over time and the academic profiles of its protagonists.
It
is surely not new to compare differences in economic performance of
diverse high cultures in world history. Contemporaries of
industrialization in the nineteenth century already highlighted European
or "Western" superiority as part of colonial and often racist
arguments, for example, in the context of the widely discussed
presentations of material culture on world fairs, starting with the
famous exhibition in London in 1851.
Michael Adas has shown, references to advanced technologies became more and more frequent among the arguments offered by nineteenth-century authors for the cultural dominance of the West9.
In scientific discourse, authors in the early 20th century like the German sociologist Max Weber discussed in detail different developmental paths of various regions of the world and sought cultural explanations for Europe's particular path to industrialization. Much later, in the 1980s and 1990s, a growing awareness of globalization processes led to renewed interest in historical explanations for different developmental paths taken by the various world regions. Since then, the centre of gravity of this debate has shifted away not unlike the swing of a pendulum. The first bestsellers included Eric Jones' The European miracle (1981) and David Landes' The wealth and poverty of nations (1998). Their authors supported the idea of Western dominance by often unduly clear-cut arguments10.
A wealth of studies emerged in the rise of global history
since the 1990s that pointed out the many blind spots in publications
such as those by Jones and Landes. Now, they argued, it was urgently
necessary not just to back the discussion about the "great divergence"
with more solid data from economic history. In particular, the issues at
stake must also be considered on the basis of well-informed research on
Asian. The title of André Gunder Frank's book, Re-Orient (1998),
symbolizes this approach well11. Particularly the "California school",
named as such because its writers taught at Californian universities,
synthesized studies specifically on the economic history of pre-modern
China, to enable a more nuanced comparative analyses.
Despite all
this contention, most of these debaters shared the conviction that
Europe's "special course" into industrialization was to some extent
contingent. British industrialization is not seen as a necessary outcome
of some particular characteristics that had evolved over centuries, but
as a result that emerged somewhat arbitrarily out of a convergence of
factors, among them the availability of coal and ores, the financial
means to invest in large technological projects, and advanced forms of
technical expertise.
Most
recently, this line of research followed by the "California school" is
being supplemented by increasingly specialized studies of non-Western
economic development, providing a more solid basis for comparative
studies12. Some core arguments of the California school have be
questioned, most prominently by the economic historian Peer Vries. He
argues that during the early modern period Britain accumulated a wealth
of factors on the economic level that allowed its transition to
industrialization whereas those possibilities were not available to
China13. At first sight this position seems to mark the pendulum's swing
back to the positions taken by Jones and Landes decades ago, albeit
based on substantial amount of research results and data which became
available since, in particular on Asian economies.
Even if the
debate on the "great divergence" clearly has an interdisciplinary
character, its most visible protagonists are economic historians and
social scientists with a historical interest. It would be hard to over
emphasise that despite the large number of publications that in one way
or another are contributing to the debate, many experts, particularly
those on non-Western cultures, are refraining from engaging in the
debate even if tacitly, although their research experience is highly
relevant to its core issues. There are surely good reasons for this
choice: an inherent problem in the debate on the "great divergence" is
that a presupposition of "Western" categories can hardly be avoided as
its starting point – most prominently, industrialization and economic
growth as the crucial events seeking explanation.
Such Eurocentric
presuppositions have, however, in principle long since been overcome in
the large community of global historians. For many of them global
history, by definition, must not presuppose "Western" categories, but
must devise categories apt for the study of diverse world regions on an
equal level. This position is connected with a more general suspicion
concerning "comparisons" of regions or cultures as such – they have too
often resulted in highlighting what "the West" had and what "the Rest"
did not have. As one of the ways out of this trap, it is usually
proposed to focus instead on concrete interactions and networks,
shifting the attention to processes of exchange and to personalities who
served as brokers between cultures.
As convincing as this
position is, one might also regret its consequences on the debate about
the "great divergence". The puzzling issue "Why Europe?" easily stirs
interest and stimulates discussion in broader audiences of historical
research among the well-informed public. It is thus somewhat deplorable
when historians refrain from explicitly incorporating their positions
into the controversy, even if they may have good reasons for taking a
fundamentally critical stance on this debate as such. Such silence quite
necessarily results in a lopsided assemblage of arguments and a lack of
relevant issues in historical expertise within the debate. As will be
argued in what follows, a related problem also holds true for the factor
of interest here, namely early modern technology.
Ways to Deal with the Factor Technology in the Debate on the Great Divergence
As has already been stressed, technology is perceived as a crucial factor by nearly all the authors in the debate on the "great divergence". They agree that it was by far the only aspect of relevance to the development of sustained economic growth. It was, however, an indispensable one, insofar as without advanced machinery and the abundant energy resources provided by fossil fuels, the rising output of goods, increase in productivity and drop in prices would not have been possible.
This focus on quantifiable factors has, however, led to a somewhat lopsided treatment of technologies in the debate. Today, the history of technology is no longer seen predominantly as a history of spectacular inventions and innovation processes. Historians of technology pay attention to a whole range of other factors such as the social and cultural settings in which diverse technologies are produced and used. The debate on the "great divergence" is still characterized by a much more schematic perspective on technology, however. One traditional strain compares the technologies of pre-modern Europe, China, India, and the Ottoman Empire only in terms of who first invented what, the performance of certain artifacts or simply regarding sheer size, as is the case of comparing the ship sizes of Zheng He's fleet with those of the European colonial powers.
It has to be stressed that this focus is as characteristic of proponents of European superiority as well as of proponents of the superiority of Asian civilizations in the pre-industrial era. Just as Jones and Landes, repeatedly highlighted the superiority and ingenuity of Western technology, John Hobson, a most fervent advocate of Asian technological superiority in the same period, used the same yardstick: innovation and large-scale technologies14. A second line of thought, as part of well-established approaches in economic history, stresses the role of technological artifacts in achieving productivity gains, for example as a response by entrepreneurs to the high wage rates during British industrialization15.
For example, one line of inquiry recently gaining momentum seeks to examine the role of macro- or micro-inventions in the productivity gains. To be sure, this is just one way of approaching the role of technology in a society. It is only one of a multitude of issues nowadays under debate among historians with expertise in the history of technology, in particular when it comes to reflections about how societies employ and evaluate technologies.
The question is thus whether such a quantitative approach to the factor "technology" suffices to understand the role technology had in societies in China, India, the Ottoman Empire and European's core regions between c. 1500 and c. 1800 and the relevance this factor thus might have had to the "great divergence". One might well argue that a merely quantitative perception of the issue of technology rather obstructs a more substantial discussion of the qualitative aspects of this factor. Along this line of thought, the discussion about technological issues in the controversy on the "great divergence" could in the future be brought to a different level.
One could, for example, explicitly turn
away from comparing the mere performance of technical artifacts and from
using yardsticks like efficiency and productivity gains, in order to
develop non-Eurocentric categories instead which might better serve to
compare technologies in different world regions. Such categories might
comprise the ways technologies were adopted and adapted to local
economic, social, and environmental conditions; how respective decisions
were influenced by political or religious structures; and which
symbolic functions such artifacts had as part of the material culture of
a given place or region. So far, however, a discussion about the
standards by which one might compare pre-industrial technologies in
different regions of the world with such rather qualitative categories
has hardly even begun16.
One thing quite clear is that
utilization of the most intricate machinery is not an appropriate
yardstick of our reflection on the ways technology is part and parcel of
a change over time in any society. An often cited example of the
problems connected to this frequently adopted approach is the employment
of milling machinery in Europe and China. While the basic elements of
this technology had been known in both cultures since about the time of
Christ's birth, and various forms of mills were being employed for
various purposes in China for centuries, China did not experience a
similar application density of grain mills as did Europe, where mills
were found in a range of places throughout the early modern period. One
of the basic reasons is that, in China, the milling of rice was simply
not necessary or adequate.
All the same, when it comes to agrarian
output, Chinese rice farming produced more calories per area than
European grain production. To use the number of mills employed as a
yardstick for technological superiority is thus as misleading. Similarly
misleading is the argument that the renunciation of carts in Arab
regions since late Antiquity in favor of camels marks a technological
regression in transportation. Research has shown that because the
climatic and environmental circumstances in which they technical choice
was made, camels were simply much more apt to fulfil transportation
purposes than carts.
Another such doubtful comparison regards the
employment of complex pumping technology for irrigation purposes as a
symbol of technological progress. Hydraulic systems such as those in
China or in the Islamic world and Persia, to a great extent without
relying on such mechanical devices, fulfilled comparable functions and
were sometimes executed on a considerably larger scale than their
European counterparts.
To be sure, mechanical technology remains
highly relevant to the study of Western industrialization. Yet the
argument advanced here is that it would be productive to discuss
pre-industrial technology on a global scale without necessarily
presupposing Eurocentric categories. There is surely enough material to
do so. In recent years a number of pioneering studies have been
published that take a closer look at Ottoman artisans, cotton production
in Asian regions, the employment of gunpowder weapons across Asia, or
the employment of technical and scientific illustrations and technical
treatises in China17.
However, these path-breaking studies seem to have not been taken comprehensively into account in scholarship on the "great divergence". An attempt to take a closer look at "technology", below the only skin-deep quantitative approaches, could also be directed at the study of technical knowledge, along the lines discussed in the following section.
Applied Science or Technical Knowledge?
Interestingly, "science" is only rarely discussed as a relevant factor in the debate over the "great divergence". By now, there seems to be an agreement that major achievements in the natural sciences in Europe, even those by such outstanding characters as Galileo and Newton, did not directly influence technological achievements in the early stages of the industrial revolution and are thus not of relevance to Europe's "special course".
This aspect is connected to the insight that technology in the early modern period and, as many researchers now argue, even far into the nineteenth and twentieth centuries, was definitely not some kind of "applied science". Therefore it cannot be said that scientific reasoning was in some way "adapted" to technological needs and thus helped to realize artefacts, procedures or machines that artisanship alone would not have succeeded in producing.
To be sure, many technical experts in
early modern Europe increasingly attempted to analyse pressing technical
problems with mathematical and geometrical tools, in particular in
civil and military engineering. In the overwhelming majority of cases,
however, they succeeded in describing in mathematical language what they
had perceived before, rather than developing new technical solutions on
the basis of scientific reasoning. For the debate on the "great
divergence", it is quite clear that it was definitely not scientific
reasoning that put early modern Britain on the path toward
industrialization.
This, however, does not mean that far-reaching
transformations of technical expertise during the early modern period
were irrelevant to technological change right from the start. Much
better than describing these transformations in terms of (applied)
science, they might be described as a whole set of interrelated
developments that resulted in the fact that technical knowledge was no
longer nearly exclusively embodied in an artisan, in the form of
personal expertise accumulated over the course of years or decades.
Since the late Middle Ages, in addition to that common form of
expertise, representational media such as technical drawings and
treatises had become part of standard practice. Towards the end of the
early modern period, such formalized technical knowledge was collected,
discussed, and taught in institutions such as scientific academies,
economic societies, and engineering schools18.
To what extent
this development which indeed influenced technical practice in early
industrialization is still a matter of debate. However, it seems evident
that, it was related to practices like the usage of scaled-down models
and measuring instruments in engineering, to field trials in
agriculture, to learned correspondence, and to privileges for
inventions, patents, and prize contests.
Authors including Joel Mokyr and Margret Jacob have recently identified this cluster of media, institutions and practices, with regard to the eighteenth century, as part of an "industrial enlightenment", to which they attach considerable relevance to the onset of British industrialization19; Other authors have questioned the top-down approach inherent in this argument and have opted for a broader analysis of technical knowledge that does more justice to a broad array of various forms of artisanal knowledge that undoubtedly produced viable economic effects in early modern Europe20.
Conclusion
For future studies on the "great divergence", this shift of focus from highlighting "science" as a factor of cross-cultural comparisons to investigating instead various bodies of formalized knowledge in different parts of the world fits well into more recent developments in a global history of science. Studies that explore – even without directly contribute – to the issue of the "great divergence" tend to look at "science" from the perspective of the "natural sciences" according to European standards, to an encompassing variety of bodies of formalized knowledge21.
Such approaches converge well with recent trends in studies
at the intersection of early modern history of science and history of
technology in Europe that increasingly tend to overcome this binary
opposition with the aim rather of writing an overarching history of
expertise in that period22.
Due to their somewhat restricted
focus on technological invention alone, the protagonists of the debate
on the "great divergence" thus far have not taken much note of these
transformations of early modern technical knowledge. A research project
headed by Patrick O'Brien at the London School of Economics mainly
introduced this perspective into reflections on the "great divergence"
by studying the generation and application of "useful and reliable
knowledge" in various world regions before the onset of
industrialization. Karel Davids, in his recent contribution to the
debate, has discussed the relation between religion and technology in
pre-modern Europe and China, with extensive reference to such newer
methodological approaches23.
He thus demonstrated that an in-depth
consideration of these media, institutions and practices is one of many
possibilities to bring the discussion of technology in this controversy
to a level transcending its study as a factor exclusively for the
generation of economic growth.
The "cultural turn" that the
history of technology as a historical sub-discipline has witnessed in
recent years offers many such possibilities for the study of how
societies in various world regions not only employed technologies as an
economically relevant factor, but also as an inherent part of their
material culture within which technology served a multitude of cultural
and symbolic functions.
The study of technical knowledge, in this panorama, shifts the focus away from some sort of "applied science" toward studying the wealth of knowledge formations that characterized, in particular, the expertise with which artisans produced viable economic effects in all regions of the world. Historians of science and technology might profit from future insights into an extended study of these levels of the "great divergence" to the same extent as representatives of other scientific disciplines and the interested public.
Notes
1.
A useful basic introduction to this debate is Jack A. Goldstone, Why
Europe? The Rise of the West in World History, 1500-1850, New York,
McGraw-Hill, 2009.
2. Kenneth Pomeranz, The Great Divergence.
China, Europe and the Making of the Modern World Economy,
Princeton/Oxford, Princeton University Press, 2000.
3. Jack A.
Goldstone, « Efflorescences and Economic Growth in World History:
Rethinking the "Rise of the West" and the Industrial Revolution »,
Journal of World History, 13, p. 323-389.
4. Rolf Peter Sieferle, Der Europäische Sonderweg. Ursachen und Faktoren, Stuttgart, Breuninger Stiftung, 2003.
5.
These authors comprise Joel Mokyr, The Lever of Riches. Technological
Creativity and Economic Progress, Oxford, Oxford University Press, 1990;
David Landes, The Wealth and Poverty of Nations. Why Some Are So Rich
and Some So Poor, New York, W. W. Norton, 1998; Michael Mitterauer,
Warum Europa? Mittelalterliche Grundlagen eines Sonderwegs, Munich, C.
H. Beck, 2003.
6. See, for example, Bishnupriya Gupta, Debin Ma, «
Europe in an Asian mirror: the Great Divergence », in Stephen
Broadberry, Kevin H. O'Rourke (eds), The Cambridge Economic History of
Modern Europe, Vol. 1 (1700-1870), Cambridge, Cambridge University
Press, 2010, p. 264-285. With ample references to previous studies, Peer
Vries, Escaping Poverty. The Origins of Modern Economic Growth,
Göttingen, V&R unipress, 2013; Roman Studer, The Great Divergence
Reconsidered. Europe, India, and the Rise to Global Economic Power,
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 2015.
7. Maxine Berg (ed.), Goods from the East, 1600-1800. Trading Eurasia, Basingstoke, Palgrave Macmillan, 2015.
8.
Frances Gies, Joseph Gies, Cathedral, Forge, and Waterwheel. Technology
and Invention in the Middle Ages, New York, Harper Collins, 1994, p.
82-104.
9. Michael Adas, Machines as the Measure of Men. Science,
Technology, and Ideologies of Western Dominance, Ithaca/London, Cornell
University Press, 1989.
10. Eric Jones, The European Miracle.
Environments, Economies and Geopolitics in the History of Europe and
Asia, Cambridge/M., MIT Press, 1981; David Landes, The Wealth and
Poverty of Nations. Why Some Are So Rich and Some Are So Poor, London,
Little/Brown, 1998.
11. André Gunder Frank, Re-Orient: Global Economy in the Asian Age, Berkeley, University of California Press, 1998.
12.
One among many examples is Prasannan Parthasarathi, Why Europe Grew
Rich and Asia Did Not. Global Economic Divergence, 1600-1850, Cambridge,
Cambridge University Press, 2011.
13. P. Vries, Escaping Poverty,
op. cit. See also his State, Economy, and the Great Divergence. Great
Britain and China 1680s-1850s, London, Bloomsbury Academic, 2015. The
arguments by Pomeranz and Vries are summarized at an earlier stage in
Kenneth Pomeranz, « Repenser le changement économique de longue durée:
la Chine, l'Europe et l'histoire comparée », dans Jean-Claude Daumas
(dir.), L'Histoire économique en mouvement entre héritages et
renouvellements, Villeneuve-d'Ascq, Presses Universitaires du
Septentrion, 2012, p. 293-310, and Peer Vries, « Un monde de
ressemblances surprenantes ? », dans id., p. 311-340.
14. John Hobson, The Eastern Origins of Western Civilization, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 2004.
15.
For this approach see, for example: Robert C. Allen, The British
Industrial Revolution in global perspective, Cambridge, Cambridge
University Press, 2009.
16. A good example of a more balanced
treatment of the history of technology in a particular epoch of Chinese
history is Francesca Bray, Technology and Society in Ming China
(1368-1644), Washington D. C., American Historical Association, 1997.
For an attempt to contextualized technological developments better in
various world regions during the Middle Millennium, see Dagmar Schäfer,
Marcus Popplow, « Technology and Innovation within Expanding Webs of
Exchange », in Benjamin Z. Kedar and Merry E. Wiesner-Hanks (eds),
Expanding Webs of Exchange and Conflict, 500 CE-1500 CE, Cambridge,
Cambridge University Press, 2015, p. 309-338.
17. Surayia Faroqhi,
Artisans of Empire. Crafts and Craftspeople under the Ottomans, London,
Tauris, 2009; Giorgio Riello, Prasannan Parthasarathi (dir.), The
Spinning World. A Global History of Cotton Textiles, Oxford, Oxford
University Press, 2009; Iqtidar Alam Khan, Gunpowder and Firearms.
Warfare in Medieval India, Oxford, Oxford University Press, 2004; Gábor
Ágoston, Guns for the Sultan. Military Power and the Weapons Industry in
the Ottoman Empire, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 2006; Peter
Lorge, The Asian Military Revolution. From Gunpowder to the Bomb,
Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 2008; Francesca Bray, Vera
Dorofeeva-Lichtmann, Georges Métailié (eds), Graphics and Text in the
Production of Technical Knowledge in China. The Warp and the Weft,
Leiden/Boston, Brill, 2007; Dagmar Schäfer, The Crafting of the 10 000
Things. Knowledge and Technology in Seventeenth-Century China, Chicago,
University of Chicago Press, 2011.
18. Marcus Popplow, «
Formalization and interaction. Towards a comprehensive history of
technology-related knowledge in early modern Europe », ISIS 106, 2015,
p. 848-856.
19. Joel Mokyr, The Enlightened Economy. An Economic
History of Britain, 1700-1850, New Haven, Yale University Press, 2009;
Margaret C. Jacob, The First Knowledge Economy. Human Capital and the
European Economy, 1750-1850, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press,
2014.
20. Liliane Hilaire-Pérez, « Technology as a public culture
in the eighteenth century: The artisans' legacy », History of Science,
45, 2007, p. 135-153.
21. See, for example, Francesca Bray, «
Science, technique, technology. Passages between matter and knowledge in
imperial Chinese agriculture », British Journal for the History of
Science, 41, 2008, p. 1-26. See also the « focus section » entitled «
Global histories of science » in ISIS 101, 2010, p. 95-158, in
particular Sujit Sivasundaram, « Sciences and the global: on methods,
questions, and theory », p. 146-158. For a reconsideration of the notion
of « science » as employed in Joseph Needham, Science and Civilisation
in China, Vol. I-VII, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 1954-2008,
see David de Saeger and Erik Weber, « Needham's Grand question
revisited: On the meaning and justification of causal claims in the
history of Chinese science », East Asian Science, Technology, and
Medicine, 33, 2011, p. 13-32. Furthermore Jürgen Renn (ed.), The
globalization of knowledge in history, Berlin, Édition Open Access,
2012; Dagmar Schäfer, « Technology and innovation in global history and
in the history of the global », in Maxine Berg (ed.), Writing the
history of the global. Challenges for the 21st century, Oxford, Oxford
university Press, 2013, p. 147-164.
22. Such approaches are cited
and discussed, for example, in the contribution to the « focus section »
entitled « Bridging concepts: Connecting and globalizing histories of
science, history of technology, and economic history » in ISIS 106,
2015, edited by Karel Davids.
23. Karel Davids, Religion,
Technology, and the Great and Little Divergences. China and Europe
Compared, c. 700-1800, Leiden, Brill, 2013. See also his contribution in
this volume.