Introductory Trade Issues: History, Institutions, and Legal Framework
Site: | Saylor Academy |
Course: | BUS403: Negotiations and Conflict Management |
Book: | Introductory Trade Issues: History, Institutions, and Legal Framework |
Printed by: | Guest user |
Date: | Tuesday, May 13, 2025, 10:42 PM |
Description
Read this summary of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), which evolved into the World Trade Organization (WTO) in 1995 and currently has 164 members. The WTO is a forum for governments to negotiate trade agreements and settle trade disputes. It operates an international system of trade rules. They are contracts that bind governments to keep their trade policies within agreed limits. Its goal is to "help producers of goods and services, exporters, and importers conduct their business while allowing governments to meet social and environmental objectives". (WTO)
Table of contents
- Introduction
- The International Economy and International Economics
- Understanding Tariffs
- Recent Trade Controversies
- The Great Depression, Smoot-Hawley, and the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act (RTAA)
- The General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT)
- The Uruguay Round
- The World Trade Organization
- Appendix A: Selected U.S. Tariffs – 2009
- Appendix B: Bound versus Applied Tariffs
Introduction
Economics is a social science whose purpose is to understand the
workings of the real-world economy. An economy is something that no one
person can observe in its entirety. We are all a part of the economy, we
all buy and sell things daily, but we cannot observe all parts and
aspects of an economy at any one time.
For this reason,
economists build mathematical models, or theories, meant to describe
different aspects of the real world. For some students, economics seems
to be all about these models and theories, these abstract equations and
diagrams. However, in actuality, economics is about the real world, the
world we all live in.
For this reason, it is important in any
economics course to describe the conditions in the real world before
diving into the theory intended to explain them. In this case, in a
textbook about international trade, it is very useful for a student to
know some of the policy issues, the controversies, the discussions, and
the history of international trade.
This first chapter provides
an overview of the real world with respect to international trade. It
explains not only where we are now but also where we have been and why
things changed along the way. It describes current trade laws and
institutions and explains why they have been implemented.
With
this overview about international trade in the real world in mind, a
student can better understand why the theories and models in the later
chapters are being developed. This chapter lays the groundwork for
everything else that follows.
This text was adapted by Saylor Academy under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-ShareAlike 3.0 License without attribution as requested by the work's original creator or licensor.
The International Economy and International Economics
International economics is growing in importance as a field of study because of the rapid integration of international economic markets. Increasingly, businesses, consumers, and governments realize that their lives are affected not only by what goes on in their own towns, state, or country but also by what is happening worldwide. Consumers can walk into their local shops today and buy goods and services from all over the world. Local businesses must compete with these foreign products. However, many of these same businesses also have new opportunities to expand their markets by selling to many consumers in other countries. The advance of telecommunications is also rapidly reducing the cost of providing services internationally. At the same time, the Internet will assuredly change the nature of many products and services as it expands markets even further.
One simple way to see the rising importance of international economics is to look at the growth of exports in the world during the past 50 or more years. Figure 1.1 "World Exports, 1948–2008 (in Billions of U.S. Dollars)" shows the annual exports measured in billions of U.S. dollars from 1948 to 2008. Recognizing that one country's exports are another country's imports, one can see the exponential growth in outflows and inflows during the past 50 years.
Figure 1.1 World Exports, 1948–2008 (in Billions of U.S. Dollars)
However, rapid growth in the value of exports does not necessarily indicate that trade is becoming more important. A better method is to look at the share of traded goods in relation to the size of the world economy. Figure 1.2 "World Exports, 1970–2008 (Percentage of World GDP)" shows world exports as a percentage of the world gross domestic product (GDP) for the years 1970 to 2008. It shows a steady increase in trade as a share of the size of the world economy. World exports grew from just over 10 percent of the GDP in 1970 to over 30 percent by 2008. Thus trade is not only rising rapidly in absolute terms; it is becoming relatively more important too.
Figure 1.2 World Exports, 1970–2008 (Percentage of World GDP)
Another indicator of world interconnectedness can be seen in changes in foreign direct investment (FDI). FDI is foreign ownership of productive activities and thus is another way foreign economic influence can affect a country. Figure 1.3 "World Inward FDI Stocks, 1980–2007 (Percentage of World GDP)" shows the stock, or the sum total value, of FDI worldwide taken as a percentage of the world GDP between 1980 and 2007. It indicates the importance of foreign ownership and influence around the world. As can be seen, the share of FDI has grown dramatically from around 5 percent of the world GDP in 1980 to over 25 percent of the GDP just 25 years later.
Figure 1.3 World Inward FDI Stocks, 1980–2007 (Percentage of World GDP)
The growth of international trade and investment has been stimulated partly by the steady decline of trade barriers since the Great Depression of the 1930s. In the post–World War II era, the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade, or GATT, prompted regular negotiations among members to reciprocally reduce tariffs (import taxes) on imported goods. During each of these regular negotiations (eight of these rounds were completed between 1948 and 1994), countries promised to reduce their tariffs on imports in exchange for concessions – that means tariffs reductions – by other GATT members.
When the Uruguay Round, the most recently completed round, was finalized in 1994, the member countries succeeded in extending the agreement to include liberalization promises in a much larger sphere of influence. Now countries not only would lower tariffs on goods trade but also would begin to liberalize the agriculture and services markets. They would eliminate the many quota systems - like the multifiber agreement in clothing - that had sprouted up in previous decades. And they would agree to adhere to certain minimum standards to protect intellectual property rights such as patents, trademarks, and copyrights. The World Trade Organization (WTO) was created to manage this system of new agreements, to provide a forum for regular discussion of trade matters, and to implement a well-defined process for settling trade disputes that might arise among countries.
As of 2009, 153 countries were members of the WTO "trade liberalization club," and many more countries were still negotiating entry. As the club grows to include more members – and if the latest round of trade liberalization talks called the Doha Round, concludes with an agreement – world markets will become increasingly open to trade and investment. Note that the Doha Round of discussions was begun in 2001 and remains uncompleted as of 2009.
Another international push for trade liberalization has come from regional free trade agreements. Over two hundred regional trade agreements worldwide have been notified or announced to the WTO. Many countries have negotiated these agreements with neighboring countries or major trading partners to promote even faster trade liberalization. In part, these have arisen because of the slow, plodding pace of liberalization under the GATT/WTO. In part, the regional trade agreements have occurred because countries have wished to promote interdependence and connectedness with important economic or strategic trade partners. In any case, the phenomenon serves to open international markets even further than achieved in the WTO.
These changes in economic patterns and the trend toward ever-increasing openness are an important aspect of the more exhaustive phenomenon known as globalization. Globalization more formally refers to the economic, social, cultural, or environmental changes that tend to interconnect peoples worldwide. Since the economic aspects of globalization are certainly the most pervasive of these changes, it is increasingly important to understand the implications of a global marketplace on consumers, businesses, and governments. That is where the study of international economics begins.
What Is International Economics?
International economics is a field of study that assesses the implications of international trade, international investment, and international borrowing and lending. There are two broad subfields within the discipline: international trade and international finance.
International trade is a field in economics that applies microeconomic models to help understand the international economy. Its content includes basic supply-and-demand analysis of international markets; firm and consumer behavior; perfectly competitive, oligopolistic, and monopolistic market structures; and the effects of market distortions. The typical course describes economic relationships among consumers, firms, factory owners, and the government.
The objective of an international trade course is to understand the effects of international trade on individuals and businesses and the effects of changes in trade policies and other economic conditions. The course develops arguments that support a free trade policy as well as arguments that support various types of protectionist policies. By the end of the course, students should better understand the centuries-old controversy between free trade and protectionism.
International finance applies macroeconomic models to help understand the international economy. Its focus is on the interrelationships among aggregate economic variables such as GDP, unemployment rates, inflation rates, trade balances, exchange rates, interest rates, and so on. This field expands basic macroeconomics to include international exchanges. Its focus is on the significance of trade imbalances, the determinants of exchange rates, and the aggregate effects of government monetary and fiscal policies. The pros and cons of fixed versus floating exchange rate systems are among the important issues addressed.
This international trade textbook begins in this chapter by discussing current and past issues and controversies relating to microeconomic trends and policies. We will highlight past trends both in implementing policies that restrict trade and in forging agreements to reduce trade barriers. It is these real-world issues that make the theory of international trade worth studying.
Key Takeaways
- International trade and investment flows have grown dramatically and consistently during the past half-century.
- International trade is a field in economics that applies microeconomic models to help understand the international economy.
- International finance focuses on the interrelationships among aggregate economic variables such as GDP, unemployment, inflation, trade balances, exchange rates, etc.
Understanding Tariffs
The
most common way to protect one's economy from import competition is to
implement a tariff: a tax on imports. Generally speaking, a tariff is
any tax or fee collected by a government. Sometimes the term "tariff" is
used in a nontrade context, as in railroad tariffs. However, the term
is more commonly used to refer to a tax on imported goods.
Tariffs
have been applied by countries for centuries and have been one of the
most common methods used to collect revenue for governments. Largely
this is because it is relatively simple to place customs officials at
the border of a country and collect a fee on goods that enter.
Administratively, a tariff is probably one of the easiest taxes to
collect. (Of course, high tariffs may induce the smuggling of goods through
nontraditional entry points, but we will ignore that problem here).
Tariffs
are worth defining early in an international trade course since changes
in tariffs represent the primary way countries either
liberalize trade or protect their economies. It isn't the only way,
though, since countries also implement subsidies, quotas, and other
types of regulations that can affect trade flows between countries.
These other methods will be defined and discussed later, but for now it
suffices to understand tariffs since they still represent the basic
policy affecting international trade patterns.
When people talk
about trade liberalization, they generally mean reducing the tariffs on
imported goods, thereby allowing the products to enter at lower cost.
Since lowering the cost of trade makes it more profitable, it will make
trade freer. A complete elimination of tariffs and other barriers to
trade is what economists and others mean by free trade. In contrast, any
increase in tariffs is referred to as protection, or protectionism.
Because tariffs raise the cost of importing products from abroad but not
from domestic firms, they have the effect of protecting the domestic
firms that compete with imported products. These domestic firms are
called import competitors.
There are two basic ways in which
tariffs may be levied: specific tariffs and ad valorem tariffs. A
specific tariff is levied as a fixed charge per unit of imports. For
example, the U.S. government levies a $0.51 specific tariff on every
wristwatch imported into the United States. Thus, if one thousand
watches are imported, the U.S. government collects $510 in tariff
revenue. In this case, $510 is collected whether the watch is a $40
Swatch or a $5,000 Rolex.
An ad valorem tariff is levied as a
fixed percentage of the value of the commodity imported. "Ad valorem" is
Latin for "on value" or "in proportion to the value". The United States levies a 2.5 percent ad valorem tariff on imported
automobiles. Thus, if $100,000 worth of automobiles are imported, the
U.S. government collects $2,500 in tariff revenue. In this case, $2,500
is collected whether two $50,000 BMWs or ten $10,000 Hyundais are
imported.
Occasionally, both a specific and an ad valorem tariff
are levied on the same product simultaneously. This is known as a
two-part tariff. For example, wristwatches imported into the United
States face the $0.51 specific tariff as well as a 6.25 percent ad
valorem tariff on the case and the strap and a 5.3 percent ad valorem
tariff on the battery. Perhaps this should be called a three-part
tariff!
As the above examples suggest, different tariffs are
generally applied to different commodities. Governments rarely apply the
same tariff to all goods and services imported into the country.
Several countries prove the exception, though. For example, Chile levies
a 6 percent tariff on every imported good, regardless of the category.
Similarly, the United Arab Emirates sets a 5 percent tariff on almost
all items, while Bolivia levies tariffs at zero percent, 2.5
percent, 5 percent, 7.5 percent, or 10 percent. Nonetheless, simple and
constant tariffs such as these are uncommon.
Thus, instead of one
tariff rate, countries have a tariff schedule that specifies the tariff
collected on every particular good and service. In the United States,
the tariff schedule is called the Harmonized Tariff Schedule (HTS) of
the United States. The commodity classifications are based on the
international Harmonized Commodity Coding and Classification System (or
the Harmonized System) established by the World Customs Organization.
Measuring Protectionism: Average Tariff Rates Around the World
One
method used to measure the degree of protectionism within an economy is
the average tariff rate. Since tariffs generally reduce imports of
foreign products, the higher the tariff, the greater the protection
afforded to the country's import-competing industries. At one time,
tariffs were perhaps the most commonly applied trade policy. Many
countries used tariffs as a primary source of funds for their government
budgets. However, as trade liberalization advanced in the second half
of the twentieth century, many other types of nontariff barriers became
more prominent.
Table 1.1, "Average Tariffs in Selected Countries
(2009)," provides a list of average tariff rates in selected countries
around the world. These rates were calculated as the simple average
tariff across more than five thousand product categories in each
country's applied tariff schedule located on the World Trade
Organization (WTO) Web site. The countries are ordered by highest to
lowest per capita income.
Country | Average Tariff Rates (%) |
---|---|
United States | 3.6 |
Canada | 3.6 |
European Community (EC) | 4.3 |
Japan | 3.1 |
South Korea | 11.3 |
Mexico | 12.5 |
Chile | 6.0 (uniform) |
Argentina | 11.2 |
Brazil | 13.6 |
Thailand | 9.1 |
China | 9.95 |
Egypt | 17.0 |
Philippines | 6.3 |
India | 15.0 |
Kenya | 12.7 |
Ghana | 13.1 |
Table 1.1 Average Tariffs in Selected Countries (2009)
Generally
speaking, average tariff rates are less than 20 percent in most
countries, although they are often quite a bit higher for agricultural
commodities. In the most developed countries, average tariffs are less
than 10 percent and often less than 5 percent. On average,
less-developed countries maintain higher tariff barriers, but many
countries that have recently joined the WTO have reduced their tariffs
substantially to gain entry.
Problems Using Average Tariffs as a Measure of Protection
The
first problem with using average tariffs as a measure of protection in a
country is that there are several different ways to calculate an
average tariff rate, and each method can give a very different
impression about the level of protection.
The tariffs in Table
1.1 "Average Tariffs in Selected Countries (2009)" are calculated as a
simple average. To calculate this rate, one simply adds up all the
tariff rates and divides by the number of import categories. One problem
with this method arises if a country has most of its trade in a few
categories with zero tariffs but has high tariffs in many categories it
would never find advantageous to import. In this case, the average
tariff may overstate the degree of protection in the economy.
This
problem can be avoided, to a certain extent, if one calculates the
trade-weighted average tariff. This measure weighs each tariff by the
share of total imports in that import category. Thus, if a country has
most of its imports in a category with very low tariffs but has many
import categories with high tariffs and virtually no imports, then the
trade-weighted average tariff would indicate a low level of protection.
The simple way to calculate a trade-weighted average tariff rate is to
divide the total tariff revenue by the total value of imports. Since
these data are regularly reported by many countries, this is a common
way to report average tariffs. To illustrate the difference, the United
States is listed in Table 1.1 "Average Tariffs in Selected Countries
(2009)" with a simple average tariff of 3.6 percent. However, in 2008
the U.S. tariff revenue collected came to $29.2 billion from imports of
goods totaling $2,126 billion, meaning that the U.S. trade-weighted
average tariff was a mere 1.4 percent.
Nonetheless, the
trade-weighted average tariff is not without flaws. For example, suppose
a country has relatively little trade because it has prohibitive
tariffs (i.e., tariffs set so high as to eliminate imports) in many
import categories. If it has some trade in a few import categories with
relatively low tariffs, then the trade-weighted average tariff would be
relatively low. After all, there would be no tariff revenue in the
categories with prohibitive tariffs. In this case, a low average tariff
could be reported for a highly protectionist country. Also, in this
case, the simple average tariff would register as a higher average
tariff and might be a better indicator of the level of protection in the
economy.
Of course, the best way to overstate the degree of protection is to use the average tariff rate on dutiable imports. This alternative measure, which is sometimes reported, only considers categories in which a tariff is actually levied and ignores all categories in which the tariff is set to zero. Since many countries today have many categories of goods with zero tariffs applied, this measure would give a higher estimate of average tariffs than most of the other measures.
The second major problem with using average tariff rates to measure the degree of protection is that tariffs are not the only trade policy used by countries. Countries also implement quotas, import licenses, voluntary export restraints, export taxes, export subsidies, government procurement policies, domestic content rules, and much more. In addition, there are a variety of domestic regulations that, for large economies at least, can and do have an impact on trade flows. None of these regulations, restrictions, or impediments to trade, affecting both imports and exports, would be captured using any of the average tariff measures. Nevertheless, these nontariff barriers can have a much greater effect on trade flows than tariffs themselves.
Key Takeaways
- Specific tariffs are assessed as a money charge per unit of the imported good.
- Ad valorem tariffs are assessed as a percentage of the value of the imported good.
- Average tariffs can be measured as a simple average across product categories or weighted by the level of imports.
- Although average tariffs are used to measure the degree of protection or openness of a country, neither measure is best because each measure has unique problems.
- In general, average tariffs are higher in developing countries and lower in developed countries.
Recent Trade Controversies
In
the spring of 2009, the world was amid the largest economic
downturn since the early 1980s. Economic production was falling and
unemployment was rising. International trade had fallen substantially
everywhere in the world, while investment both domestically and
internationally dried up.
The source of these problems was the
bursting of a real estate bubble. Bubbles are fairly common in both real
estate and stock markets. A bubble describes a steady and persistent
increase in prices in a market – in this case, in the real estate
markets in the United States and abroad. When bubbles are developing,
many market observers argue that the prices reflect true
values despite a sharp and unexpected increase. These justifications
fool many people into buying the products in the hope that the prices
will continue to rise and generate a profit.
When the bubble
bursts, the demand driving the price increases ceases and many participants begin to sell off their product to realize their
profit. When this occurs, prices quickly plummet. The dramatic drop in
real estate prices in the United States in 2007 and 2008 left many
financial institutions near bankruptcy. These financial market
instabilities finally spilled over into the real sector (i.e., the
sector where goods and services are produced), contributing not only to a
world recession but also to a new popular attitude that capitalism and
free markets may not be working very well. This attitude change may fuel
the antiglobalization sentiments that were growing during the previous
decade.
As the current economic crisis unfolded, there were
numerous suggestions about similarities between this recession and the
Great Depression in the 1930s. One big concern was that countries might
revert to protectionism to try to save jobs for domestic workers. This
is precisely what many countries did at the onset of the Great
Depression, and it is widely believed that that reaction made the
Depression worse rather than better.
Since the economic crisis
began in late 2008, national leaders have regularly vowed to avoid
protectionist pressures and maintain current trade liberalization
commitments made under the World Trade Organization (WTO) and individual
free trade agreements. However, at the same time, countries have raised
barriers to trade in various subtle ways. For example, the United
States revoked a promise to maintain a program allowing Mexican trucks
to enter the United States under the North American Free Trade Agreement
(NAFTA), it included "Buy American" provisions it its economic stimulus
package, it initiated a special safeguards action against Chinese tire
imports, and it brought a case against China at the WTO. Although many
of these actions are legal and allowable under U.S. international
commitments, they are irritating to U.S. trading partners
and indicative of the rising pressure to implement policies favorable to
domestic businesses and workers. Most other countries have taken
similar, albeit subtle, protectionist actions.
Nevertheless,
this rising protectionism contradicts a second popular sentiment
among people seeking to achieve greater liberalization and openness in
international markets. For example, as the recession began, the United
States had several free trade areas waiting to be approved by the U.S.
Congress: one with South Korea, another with Colombia, and a third with
Panama. In addition, the United States has participated in talks
recently with many Pacific Rim countries to forge a Trans-Pacific
Partnership (TPP) that could liberalize trade around the region.
Simultaneously, free trade area discussions continue among many other
country pairings around the world.
This current ambivalence among
countries and policymakers is nothing new. Since the Great Depression,
trade policymaking around the world can be seen as a tug of war between
proponents and opponents of trade liberalization. Even as free trade
advocates have achieved trade expansions and liberalizations, free trade
opponents have often achieved market-closing policies simultaneously;
three steps forward toward trade liberalization are often coupled with
two steps back at the same time.
To illustrate this point, we
continue with a discussion of recent initiatives for trade
liberalization and some of the efforts to resist these liberalization
movements. We'll also look back to see how the current policies and
discussions have been shaped by events in the past century.
Doha and WTO
The
Doha Round is the name of the current round of trade liberalization
negotiations undertaken by WTO member countries. The objective is for
all participating countries to reduce trade barriers from their present
levels for trade in goods, services, and agricultural products; to
promote international investment; and to protect intellectual property
rights. In addition, member countries discuss improvements in procedures
that outline the rights and responsibilities of the member countries.
Member countries decided that a final agreement should place special
emphasis on changes targeting the needs of developing countries and the
world's poor and disadvantaged. As a result, the Doha Round is sometimes
called the Doha Development Agenda, or DDA.
The Doha Round was
begun at the WTO ministerial meeting held in Doha, Qatar, in November
2001. It is the first round of trade liberalization talks under the
auspices of the WTO, which was founded in 1994 in the final General
Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) round of talks, the Uruguay Round.
Because missed deadlines are commonplace in the history of GATT talks,
an old joke is that GATT really means the "General Agreement to Talk and
Talk".
In anticipation, WTO members decided to place strict
deadlines for different agreement phases. By adhering to the
deadlines, countries were more assured that the talks would be completed
on schedule in the summer of 2005 – but the talks weren't. So members
pushed off the deadline to 2006, and then to 2007, and then to 2008,
always reporting that an agreement was near. As of 2009, the Doha Round
has still not been completed, testifying to the difficulty of getting
153 member countries to conceive of a trade liberalization agreement
that all countries can accept mutually.
This is an important
point: WTO rounds (and the GATT rounds before them) are never finalized
until every member country agrees to the terms and conditions. Each
country offers a set of trade-liberalizing commitments, or promises, and
in return receives the trade-liberalizing commitments made by its 152
potential trading partners. This is a much stronger requirement than
majority voting, wherein coalitions can force other members into
undesirable outcomes. Thus one reason this round has so far failed is
because some countries believe that the others are offering too little
liberalization relative to the liberalization they themselves are
offering.
The DDA is especially complex, not only because 153
countries must reach a consensus, but also because there are so many
trade-related issues under discussion. Countries discuss not only tariff
reductions on manufactured goods but also changes in agricultural
support programs, regulations affecting services trade, intellectual
property rights policy and enforcement, and procedures involving trade
remedy laws, to name just a few. Reaching an agreement that every
country is happy about across all these issues may be more than the
system can handle. We'll have to wait to see whether the Doha Round ever
finishes to know if it is possible. Even then, there is some chance an
agreement that is achievable may be so watered down that it doesn't
result in much trade liberalization.
The primary stumbling block
in the Doha Round (and the previous Uruguay Round too) has been
insufficient commitments on agricultural liberalization, especially by
the developed countries. Today, agriculture remains the most heavily
protected industry around the world. In addition to high tariffs at the
borders, most countries offer subsidies to farmers and dairy producers,
all of which affects world prices and international trade. Developing
countries believe that the low world prices for farm products caused by
subsidies in rich countries both prevents them from realizing their
comparative advantages and stymies economic development. However,
convincing developed country farmers to give up long-standing handouts
from their governments has been a difficult to impossible endeavor.
To
their credit, developed countries have suggested that they may be
willing to accept greater reductions in agricultural subsidies if
developing countries would substantially reduce their very high tariff
bindings on imported goods and bind most or all of their imported
products. Developing countries have argued, however, that because this
is the Doha "Development" Round, they shouldn't be asked to make many
changes at all to their trade policies; rather, they argue that changes
should be tilted toward greater market access from developing into
developed country markets.
Of course, this is not the only
impasse in the discussions, as there are many other issues on the
agenda. Nevertheless, agricultural liberalization will surely remain one
of the major stumbling blocks to continued trade liberalization
efforts. And the Doha Round is not dead yet, since continuing
discussions behind the spotlight reflect at least some sentiment worldwide that further trade liberalization is a worthy goal. But this
is not a sentiment shared by all, and indeed opponents almost prevented
this WTO round from beginning in the first place. To understand why, we
must go back two years to the Doha Round commencement in Seattle,
Washington, in December 1999.
The WTO Seattle Ministerial – 1999
Every
two years, the WTO members agreed to hold a ministerial meeting
bringing together, at minimum, the trade ministers of the member
countries to discuss WTO issues. In 1999, the ministerial was held in
Seattle, Washington, in the United States, and because it was over five
years since the last round of trade discussions had finished, many
members thought it was time to begin a new round of trade talks. There
is a well-known "bicycle theory" about international trade talks that
says that forward momentum must be maintained or else, like a bicycle,
liberalization efforts will stall.
And so the WTO countries
decided by 1999 to begin a new "Millennial Round" of trade
liberalization talks and to kick off the discussions in Seattle in
December 1999. However, two things happened, the first attesting to the
difficulty of getting agreement among so many countries and the second
attesting to the growing opposition to the principles of free trade
itself.
Shortly before the ministers met, they realized that
there was not even sufficient agreement among governments about what the
countries should discuss in the new round. For example, the United
States was opposed to any discussion about trade remedy laws, whereas
many developing countries were eager to discuss revisions. Consequently,
because no agreement - even about what to talk about - could be
reached, the start of the round was postponed.
The second result
of the meeting was a cacophony of complaints that rose up from the
thousands of protesters who gathered outside the meetings. This result
was more profound if only because the resulting disturbances, including
property damage and numerous arrests, brought the issues of trade and
the WTO to the international stage. Suddenly, the world saw that there
was substantial opposition to the principles of the WTO in promoting
trade and expanded globalization.
These protests at the Seattle
Ministerial were perhaps directed not solely at the WTO itself but
instead at a variety of issues brought to the forefront by
globalization. Some protesters were there to protest environmental
degradation and were worried that current development was unsustainable,
others were protesting child labor and unsafe working conditions in
developing countries, and still others were concerned about the loss of
domestic jobs due to international competition. In many ways, the
protesters were an eclectic group consisting of students, labor union
members, environmentalists, and even some anarchists.
After
Seattle, groups sometimes labeled "antiglobalization groups" began
organizing protests at other prominent international governmental
meetings, including the biannual World Bank and International Monetary
Fund (IMF) meetings, the meeting of the G8 countries, and the World
Economic Forum at Davos, Switzerland. The opposition to freer trade, and
globalization more generally, was on the rise. At the same time,
though, national governments continued to press for more international
trade and investment through other means.
Ambivalence about Globalization since the Uruguay Round
Objectively
speaking, ambivalence about trade and globalization seems to best
characterize the decades of the 1990s and 2000s. Although this was a
time of rising protests and opposition to globalization, it was also a
time in which substantial movements to freer trade occurred. What
follows are some events of the last few decades highlighting this
ambivalence.
First off, trade liberalization became all the rage
around the world by the late 1980s. The remarkable success of
outward-oriented economies such as South Korea, Taiwan, Hong Kong, and
Singapore - known collectively as the East Asian Tigers - combined with
the relatively poor performance of inward-oriented economies in Latin
America, Africa, India, and elsewhere led to a resurgence of support for
trade.
Because the Uruguay Round of the GATT was on its way to
creating the WTO, many countries decided to jump on the liberalizing
bandwagon by joining the negotiations to become founding members of the
WTO. One hundred twenty-three countries were members of the WTO upon its
inception in 1995, only to grow to 153 members by 2009.
Perhaps
the most important new entrant into the WTO was China in 2001. China had
wanted to be a founding member of the WTO in 1995 but was unable to
overcome the accession hurdle. You see, any country that is already a
WTO member has the right to demand trade liberalization concessions from
newly acceding members. Since producers around the world were fearful
of competition from China, most countries demanded more stringent
liberalization commitments than were usually expected from other
acceding countries at a similar level of economic development. As a
result, it took longer for China to gain entry than for most other
countries.
But at the same time that many developing countries
were eager to join the WTO, beliefs in freer trade and the WTO were
reversing in the United States. Perhaps the best example was the
struggle for the U.S. president to secure trade-negotiating authority.
First, a little history.
Article 1, section 8 of the U.S.
Constitution states, "The Congress shall have the power…to regulate
commerce with foreign nations." This means that decisions about trade
policies must be made by the U.S. Senate and House of Representatives, not by the U.S. president. Despite this, the central agency in trade
negotiations today is the United States Trade Representative (USTR), an
executive branch (or presidential) agency. The reason for this
arrangement is that the U.S. Congress has ceded authority for these
activities to the USTR. One such piece of enabling legislation is known
as trade promotion authority (TPA).
TPA enables the U.S.
president, or more specifically the USTR, to negotiate trade
liberalization agreements with other countries. The legislation is known
as fast-track authority because it provides for expedited procedures in
the approval process by the U.S. Congress. More specifically, for any
trade agreement the president presents to the Congress, Congress will
vote the agreement, in its entirety, up or down in a yea or nay vote.
Congress agrees not to amend or change in any way the contents of the
negotiated agreement. The fast-track procedure provides added
credibility to U.S. negotiators since trade agreement partners will know
the U.S. Congress cannot change the details upon review.
TPA has
been given to the U.S. president in various guises since the 1930s. In
the post–World War II era, authority was granted to the president to
negotiate successive GATT rounds. A more recent incarnation was granted
to the president in the Trade Act of 1974. TPA enabled negotiations for
the U.S.-Israel free trade area (FTA) in 1985 and NAFTA in 1993.
However, this authority expired in 1994 under President Clinton and was
never reinstated during the remainder of his presidency. The failure to
extend TPA signified the growing discontent, especially in the U.S.
House of Representatives, with trade liberalization.
When George
W. Bush became president, he wanted to push for more trade
liberalization through the expansion of FTAs with regional and strategic
trade partners. He managed to gain a renewal of TPA in 2001 (with
passage in the House by just one vote, 216 to 215). This enabled
President Bush to negotiate and implement a series of FTAs with Chile,
Singapore, Australia, Morocco, Jordan, Bahrain, Oman, Central America
and the Dominican Republic, and Peru. Awaiting congressional approval
(as of December 2009) are FTAs with South Korea, Colombia, and Panama.
Despite
these advances toward trade liberalization, TPA expired in 2007 and has
not yet been renewed by the U.S. Congress, again representing the
ambivalence of U.S. policymakers to embrace freer trade. Another
indication is the fact that the FTAs with South Korea, Colombia, and
Panama were submitted for approval to Congress before the deadline for
TPA expired in 2007 and these agreements still have not been brought
forward for a vote by the U.S. Congress.
While the United States
slows its advance toward freer trade, other countries around the world
continue to push forward. There are new FTAs between China and the
Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) countries, Japan and the
Philippines, Thailand and Chile, Pakistan and China, and Malaysia and
Sri Lanka, along with several other new pairings.
Future
prospects for trade liberalization versus trade protections are quite
likely to depend on the length and severity of the present economic
crisis. If the crisis abates soon, trade liberalization may return to
its past prominence. However, if the crisis continues for several more
years and if unemployment rates remain much higher than usual for an
extended time, then demands for more trade protection may increase
significantly. Economic crises have proved in the past to be a major
contributor to high levels of protection. Indeed, as was mentioned
previously, there is keen awareness today that the world may stumble
into the trade policy mistakes of the Great Depression. Much of the
trade liberalization that has occurred since then can be traced to the
desire to reverse the effects of the Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act of 1930.
Thus to better understand the current references to our past history,
the story of the Great Depression is told next.
Key Takeaways
- Recent support for trade liberalization is seen in the establishment of numerous free trade areas and the participation of many countries in the Doha Round of trade talks.
- Recent opposition to trade liberalization is seen in national responses to the financial cƒrisis, the protest movement at the Seattle Ministerial and other venues, and the failure in the United States to grant trade promotion authority to the president.
The Great Depression, Smoot-Hawley, and the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act (RTAA)
Perhaps
the greatest historical motivator for trade liberalization since World
War II was the experience of the Great Depression. The Depression
ostensibly began with the crash of the U.S. stock market in late 1929.
Quite rapidly thereafter, the world economy began to shrink at an
alarming pace. In 1930, the U.S. economy shrank by 8.6 percent and the
unemployment rate rose to 8.9 percent. With the contraction came a
chorus of calls for protection of domestic industries facing competition
from imported products.
For U.S. workers, a tariff bill to
substantially raise protection was already working its way through the
legislature when the economic crisis hit. The objective of higher
tariffs was to increase the cost of imported goods so that U.S.
consumers would spend their money on U.S. products instead. By doing so,
U.S. jobs could be saved in the import-competing industries. Many
economists at the time disagreed with this analysis and thought the high
tariffs would make things worse. In May 1930, 1,028 economists signed a
petition protesting the tariff act and beseeched President Hoover to
veto the bill. Despite these objections, in June of 1930 the
Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act (aka the Tariff Act of 1930), which raised
average tariffs to as much as 60 percent, was passed into law.
However,
because higher U.S. tariffs also injured the foreign companies that
were exporting into the U.S. market and because the foreign economies
were also stagnating and suffering from rising unemployment, they
responded to the Smoot-Hawley tariffs with higher tariffs of their own
in retaliation. Within several months, numerous U.S. trade partners
responded by protecting their own domestic industries with higher trade
barriers. The effect was a dramatic drop in international trade flows
throughout the world and quite possibly a deepening of the economic
crisis.
In subsequent years, the Depression did get much worse.
The U.S. economy continued to contract at double-digit rates for several
more years, and the unemployment rate peaked in 1933 at 24.9 percent.
When Franklin Roosevelt ran for president in 1932, he spoke against the
high tariffs. By 1934, a new attitude accepting the advantages of more
liberal trade took hold in the U.S. Congress, which passed the
Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act (RTAA). The RTAA authorized the U.S.
president to negotiate bilateral tariff reduction agreements with other
countries.
In practice, the president could send his agents to
another country, say Mexico, to offer tariff reductions on a collection
of imported items in return for tariff reductions by Mexico on another
set of items imported from the United States. Once both sides agreed to
the quid pro quo, the agreements would be brought back to the United
States and the Mexican governments for approval and passage into law.
Over sixty bilateral deals were negotiated under the RTAA, and it set in
motion a process of trade liberalization that would continue for
decades to come.
The RTAA is significant for two reasons. First,
it was one of the earliest times when the U.S. Congress granted trade
policymaking authority directly to the president. In later years, this
practice continued with congressional approval for presidential trade
promotion authority (TPA; aka fast-track authority) that was used to
negotiate other trade liberalization agreements. Second, the RTAA served
as a model for the negotiating framework of the General Agreement on
Tariffs and Trade (GATT). Under the GATT, countries would also offer
"concessions," meaning tariff reductions on imports, in return for
comparable concessions from the other GATT members. The main difference
is that the RTAA involved bilateral concessions, whereas the GATT was
negotiated in a multilateral environment. More on the GATT next.
Key Takeaways
- The Great Depression inspired a great wave of protectionism around the world beginning with the Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act in the United States in 1930.
- The Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act (RTAA) started a wave of trade liberalization.
- The RTAA was important because it gave trade policymaking authority to the U.S. president and because it served as a model for the GATT.
The General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT)
The
General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) was never designed to be a
stand-alone agreement. Instead, it was meant to be just one part of a
much broader agreement to establish an International Trade Organization
(ITO). The ITO was intended to promote trade liberalization by
establishing guidelines or rules that member countries would agree to
adopt. The ITO was conceived during the Bretton Woods conference
attended by the main allied countries in New Hampshire in 1944 and was
seen as complementary to two other organizations also conceived there:
the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the World Bank. The IMF would
monitor and regulate the international fixed exchange rate system, the
World Bank would assist with loans for reconstruction and development,
and the ITO would regulate international trade.
The ITO never
came into existence, however. Although a charter was drawn, the U.S.
Congress never approved it. The main concern was that the agreement
would force unwelcome domestic policy changes, especially with respect
to wage and employment policies. Because the United States would not
participate, other countries had little incentive to participate.
Nonetheless, the United States, Britain, and other allied countries
maintained a strong commitment to the reduction of tariffs on
manufactured goods. Tariffs still remained high in the aftermath of the
Depression-era increases. Thus, as discussions over the ITO charter
proceeded, the GATT component was finalized early and signed by
twenty-three countries in 1948 as a way of jump-starting the trade
liberalization process.
The GATT consists of a set of promises,
or commitments, that countries make to each other regarding their own
trade policies. The goal of the GATT is to make trade freer (i.e., to
promote trade liberalization), and thus the promises countries make must
involve reductions in trade barriers. Countries that make these
commitments and sign on to the agreement are called signatory countries.
The discussions held before the commitments are decided are called
negotiating rounds. Each round is generally given a name tied either to
the location of the meetings or to a prominent figure. There were eight
rounds of negotiation under the GATT: the Geneva Round (1948), the
Annecy Round (1950), the Torquay Round (1951), the Geneva II Round
(1956), the Dillon Round (1962), the Kennedy Round (1967), the Tokyo
Round (1979), and the Uruguay Round (1994). Most importantly, the
agreements are reached by consensus. A round finishes only when every
negotiating country is satisfied with the promises it and all of its
negotiating partners are making. The slogan sometimes used is "Nothing
Is Agreed Until Everything Is Agreed."
The promises, or
commitments, countries make under the GATT take two forms. First, there
are country-specific and product-specific promises. For example, a
country (say, the United States) may agree to reduce the maximum tariff
charged on a particular item (say, refrigerator imports) to a particular
percentage (say, 10 percent). This maximum rate is called a tariff
binding, or a bound tariff rate.
In each round, every
participating country offers concessions, which involve a list of new
tariff bindings - one for every imported product. To achieve trade
liberalization, the tariff bindings must be lower than they were
previously. However, it is important to note that there is no
harmonization of tariff bindings. At the end of a round, signatory
countries do not end up with the same tariff rates.
Instead, each
country enters a round with a unique tariff set on every item. The
expectation in the negotiating round is that each country will ratchet
its tariffs downward, on average, from its initial levels. Thus, if
Country A enters the discussions with a 10 percent tariff on
refrigerator imports, while Country B has a 50 percent tariff, then a
typical outcome to the round may have A lowering its tariff binding to 7
percent, while B lowers its to 35 percent - both 30 percent reductions
in the tariff binding. Both countries have liberalized trade, but the
GATT has not required them to adhere to the same trade policies.
Some
countries, especially developing countries, maintain fairly high bound
tariffs but have decided to reduce the actual tariff to a level below
the bound rate. This tariff is called the applied tariff. Lowering
tariffs unilaterally is allowable under the GATT, as is raising the
applied rate up to the bound rate.
There is a second form of promise that GATT countries
make that is harmonized. These promises involve acceptance of certain
principles of behavior with respect to international trade policies.
Here, too, there are two types of promises: the first involves core
principles regarding nondiscrimination and the second involves allowable
exceptions to these principles.
Nondiscrimination
One of the key principles of the GATT, one that signatory countries agree to adhere to, is the nondiscriminatory treatment of traded goods. This means countries assure that their own domestic regulations will not affect one country's goods more or less favorably than another country's and will not treat their own goods more favorably than imported goods. There are two applications of nondiscrimination: most-favored nation and national treatment.
Most-Favored Nation
Most-favored nation (MFN)
refers to the nondiscriminatory treatment toward identical or highly
substitutable goods coming from two different countries. For example, if
the United States applies a tariff of 2.6 percent on printing press
imports from the European Union (EU, one World Trade Organization [WTO]
country), then it must apply a 2.6 percent tariff on printing press
imports from every other WTO member country. Since all the countries
must be treated identically, MFN is a bit of a misnomer since it seems
to suggest that one country is most favored, whereas in actuality, it
means that countries are equally favored.
The confusion the term
generates led the United States in the 1990s to adopt an alternative
phrase, normal trade relations (NTR), for use in domestic legislation.
This term is a better description of what the country is offering when a
new country enters the WTO or when a non-WTO country is offered the
same tariff rates as its WTO partner countries. As such, these are two
ways to describe the same thing: that is, MFN ≡ NTR.
National Treatment
National treatment refers to the nondiscriminatory treatment of identical or highly substitutable domestically produced goods with foreign goods once the foreign products have cleared customs. Thus it is allowable to discriminate by applying a tariff on imported goods that would not be applied to domestic goods. Still, once the product has passed through customs it must be treated identically. This norm applies then to both state and local taxes, as well as regulations such as those involving health and safety standards. For example, if a state or provincial government applies a cigarette tax, then national treatment requires that the same tax rate be applied equally on domestic and foreign cigarettes. Similarly, national treatment would prevent a government from regulating lead-painted imported toys to be sold but not lead-painted domestic toys; if lead is to be regulated, all toys must be treated the same.
GATT Exceptions
There are several situations in which countries can violate GATT nondiscrimination principles and previous commitments such as tariff bindings. These represent allowable exceptions that, when implemented according to the guidelines, are GATT sanctioned or GATT legal. The most important exceptions are trade remedies and free trade area allowances.
Trade Remedies
An
important class of exceptions is known as trade remedies. These are
laws that enable domestic industries to request increases in import
tariffs that are above the bound rates and are applied in a
discriminatory fashion. They are called remedies because they are
intended to correct for unfair trade practices and unexpected changes in
trade patterns that are damaging to those industries that compete with
imports.
These remedies are in the GATT largely because these
procedures were already a part of the laws of the United States and
other allied countries when the GATT was first conceived. Since
application of these laws would clearly violate the basic GATT
principles of nondiscrimination, exceptions were written into the
original agreement, and these remain today. As other countries have
joined the GATT/WTO over the years, these countries have also adopted
these same laws, since the agreement allows for them. As a result, this
legal framework, established in the United States and other developed
countries almost a century ago, has been exported to most other
countries worldwide and has become the basic method of altering
trade policies from the commitments made in previous GATT rounds.
Today,
the trade remedy laws represent the primary legal method WTO countries
can use to raise their levels of protection for domestic industries. By
binding countries to maximum levels of protection, the GATT and WTO
agreements eliminate their national sovereignty concerning higher
trade barriers. Countries are always free to lower trade
barriers unilaterally without violating the agreements. The
trade remedy laws offer a kind of safety valve, because in certain
prescribed circumstances, countries can essentially renege on their
promises.
Antidumping
Antidumping laws protect
domestic import-competing firms that can show that foreign imported
products are being "dumped" in the domestic market. Since dumping is
often considered an unfair trade practice, antidumping is an
unfair trade law. Dumping is defined in several different ways. Dumping generally means selling a product at an unfair, or less than
reasonable, price. More specifically, dumping is defined as (1) sales in
a foreign market at a price less than in the home market, (2) sales in a
foreign market at a price that is less than average production costs,
or (3) if sales in the home market do not exist, sales in one foreign
market at a price that is less than the price charged in another foreign
market. The percentage by which the actual price must be raised to
reach the fair or reasonable price is called the dumping margin. For
example, if a firm sells its product in its home market for $12 but
sells it in a foreign market for $10, then the dumping margin is 20
percent since a 20 percent increase in the $10 price will raise it to
$12.
Any import-competing industry is allowed to petition its own
government for protection under its antidumping law. Protection in the
form of an antidumping (AD) duty (i.e., a tariff on imports) can be
provided if two conditions are satisfied. First, the government must
show that dumping, as defined above, is actually occurring. Second, the
government must show that the import-competing firms are suffering from,
or are threatened with, material injury as a result of the dumped
imports. Injury might involve a reduction in revenues, a loss of profit,
declining employment, or other indicators of diminished well-being. If
both conditions are satisfied, then an AD duty set equal to the dumping
margin can be implemented. After the Uruguay Round, countries agreed
that AD duties should remain in place for no more than five years before
a review (called a sunset review) must be conducted to determine if the
dumping is likely to recur. If a recurrence of dumping is likely, the
AD duties may be extended.
Normally, AD investigations determine
different dumping margins, even for firms from the same
country. When AD duties are applied, these firms will have
separate tariffs applied to their products. Thus the action is highly
discriminatory and would normally violate MFN treatment. The increase in
the tariff would also raise it above the bound tariff rate the country
reached in the latest negotiating round. However, Article 6 of the
original GATT allows this exception.
Antisubsidy
Antisubsidy
laws provide protection to domestic import-competing firms that can show
that foreign imported products are being directly subsidized by the
foreign government. Since foreign subsidies are considered an unfair
trade practice, antisubsidy is considered an unfair trade law. The
subsidies must be ones that are targeted at the export of a particular
product. These are known as specific subsidies. In contrast, generally
available subsidies, those that apply to both export firms and domestic
firms equally, are not actionable under this provision. The percentage
of the subsidy provided by the government is known as the subsidy
margin.
Import-competing firms have two recourses in the face of a
foreign government subsidy. First, they can appeal directly to the WTO
using the dispute settlement procedure. Second, they can petition
their own government under their domestic antisubsidy laws. In either
case, they must demonstrate two things: (1) that a subsidy is being
provided by the foreign government and (2) that the resulting imports
have caused injury to the import-competing firms. If both conditions are
satisfied, then a country may implement a countervailing duty (CVD) -
that is, a tariff on imports set equal to the subsidy margin. As with AD
duties, CVDs should remain in place for no more than five years before a
sunset review must be conducted to determine if the subsidies continue.
If they are still in place, the CVD may be extended.
Since CVDs
are generally applied against one country's firms but not another's, the
action is discriminatory and would normally violate MFN treatment. The
higher tariff would also raise it above the bound tariff rate the
country reached in the latest negotiating round. Nonetheless, Article 6
of the original GATT allows this exception.
Safeguards
Safeguard
laws (aka escape clauses) protect domestic
import-competing firms that can demonstrate two things: (1) that a surge
of imported products has caused disruption in the market for a
particular product and (2) that the surge has substantially caused, or
threatens to cause, serious injury to the domestic import-competing
firms. The term serious injury means that the injury must be
more severe than the injury cause in AD and antisubsidy cases. Since
import surges are not generally considered under the control of
the exporting firms or government, safeguard laws are not considered
unfair trade laws.
In the event both conditions are satisfied, a
country may respond by implementing either tariffs or quotas to protect
its domestic industry. If tariffs are used, they are to be implemented
in a nondiscriminatory fashion, meaning they are executed equally
against all countries. However, if quotas are used, they may be
allocated in a way that favors some trading partners more than others.
Safeguard actions are also intended to be temporary, lasting no more
than four years.
As with antidumping and antisubsidy cases,
because a safeguard response involves higher levels of protection, it
will likely conflict with the previously agreed bound tariff rates and
thus violate the GATT principles. However, Article 19 of the GATT, the
so-called escape clause, provides for an exception to the general rules
in this case.
Because safeguard actions in effect take away some
of the concessions a country has made to others, countries are supposed
to give something back in return. An example of acceptable compensation
would be the reduction of tariffs on some other items. This extra
requirement, together with the need to establish serious rather than
material injury, have contributed to making the use of safeguard actions
less common relative to antidumping and antisubsidy actions.
China's
Special Safeguards. When China was accepted as a WTO member country in
2001, it agreed to many demands made by other WTO members. One such
provision requested by the United States was allowance for a "special
safeguard provision". The agreement reached allowed the United States
and all other WTO countries to implement additional safeguard provisions
on specific products from China that might suddenly flood their
markets.
One important concern at the time was the surge of
textile and apparel products that might come after the expiration of the
quota system in 2005 under the Uruguay Round's Agreement on Textiles
and Clothing. As a stopgap, countries were allowed to reintroduce quotas
or other barriers in the event that imports from China surged in once
the official quotas were gone. Both the United States and the EU
implemented increased protections in 2005, and China did not enjoy the
full benefit of the quota elimination until this safeguard provision
expired in 2008.
Additional special safeguards are in place to
protect against import surges of other products from China, and these do
not expire until 2014. (In the United States, these are called section
421 cases.) Although these provisions are similar to the standard
safeguards, they are more lenient in defining an actionable event.
Free Trade Areas
One
other common situation requires an exception to the rules of the
GATT/WTO. Many countries have decided to take multiple paths toward
trade liberalization. The multilateral approach describes the process of
the GATT, whereby many countries simultaneously reduce their trade
barriers, but not to zero. The alternative approach is referred to as
regionalism, whereby two to several countries agree to reduce their
tariffs and other barriers to zero - but only among themselves. This is
called a regional approach since most times the free trade partners are
nearby, or at the very least are significant trading partners (though
this isn't always the case).
In principle, a free trade agreement
means free trade will be implemented on all products traded between the
countries. In practice, free trade areas often fall short. First, they
are rarely implemented immediately; instead, they are put into place
over a time horizon of ten, fifteen, or even twenty or more years. Thus
many free trade areas (FTAs) today are really in transition to freer
trade. Second, FTAs sometimes exempt some products from liberalization.
This occurs because of strong political pressure by some domestic
industries. If a substantial number of products are exempted, the area
is known as a preferential trade arrangement, or a PTA.
Perhaps
the most important free trade area implemented in the past fifty years
was the European Economic Community formed by the major countries in
Western Europe in 1960 that ultimately led to the formation of the
European Union in 1993. The term "union" refers to the fact that the
area is now a customs union that not only includes free trade in goods
and services but also allows for the mobility of workers and other
factors of production. In addition, some of the core European countries
have taken it one step further by creating and using the euro as a
common currency, thus establishing a monetary union in addition to the
customs union.
In the United States, an FTA was first implemented
with Israel in 1986. An FTA with Canada in 1988 and the inclusion of
Mexico with Canada to form the North American Free Trade Agreement
(NAFTA) followed. Since the turn of the millennium, the United States
has implemented FTAs with Jordan, Bahrain, Morocco, Singapore, Chile,
Australia, the Central American Free Trade Agreement - Dominican
Republic (CAFTA-DR), and Peru.
An FTA violates the GATT/WTO
principle of most-favored nation because MFN requires countries to offer
their most liberal trade policy to all GATT/WTO members. When an FTA is
formed, the most liberal policy will become a zero tariff, or free
trade. However, the original GATT carved out an exception to this rule
by including Article 24. Article 24 allows countries to pair up and form
free trade areas as long as the FTA moves countries significantly close
to free trade and as long as countries notify the GATT/WTO of each new
agreement. The simple logic is that an FTA is in the spirit of the GATT
since it does involve trade liberalization.
As of 2009, over two
hundred FTAs have been notified either to the GATT or the WTO. Many of
these have been started in the past fifteen to twenty years, suggesting
that regional approaches to trade liberalization have become more
popular, especially as progress in the multilateral forum has slowed.
This trend has also fueled debate about the most effective way to
achieve trade liberalization. For example, is the regional approach a
substitute or complement to the multilateral approach?
Key Takeaways
- The most-favored nation (MFN) principle of the GATT requires countries to provide nondiscriminatory treatment between identical or highly substitutable goods from two countries.
- The national treatment principle of the GATT requires countries to provide nondiscriminatory treatment between identical or highly substitutable goods produced domestically and those imported from another country.
- Trade remedy laws such as antidumping, antisubsidy, and safeguards provide GATT-allowable exceptions to previous commitments and the fundamental principles.
- Although bilateral or regional free trade areas violate MFN, they are allowed by GATT because they are consistent with the goal of trade liberalization.
The Uruguay Round
The Uruguay Round was the last of eight
completed rounds of the GATT. Discussion for the round began in
Montevideo, Uruguay, in 1986, and it was hoped that the round would be
completed by 1990. However, impasses were frequent, and the round was
not finalized until 1994. One reason for the delay is that this round
incorporated many new issues in the negotiations.
In earlier
rounds, the primary focus was always a continuing reduction in the bound
tariff rates charged on imported manufactured goods. As a result of
seven completed GATT rounds, by the mid-1980s tariffs in the main
developed countries were as low as 5 percent to 10 percent and there was
less and less room for further liberalization. At the same time, there
were a series of trade issues that sidestepped the GATT trade
liberalization efforts over the years. In those areas - like
agriculture, textiles and apparel, services, and intellectual property -
trade barriers of one sort or another persisted. Thus the ambitious
objective of the Uruguay Round was to bring those issues to the table
and try to forge a more comprehensive trade liberalization agreement.
The goals were reached by establishing a series of supplementary
agreements on top of the traditional tariff reduction commitments of the
GATT. A few of these agreements are highlighted next.
The Agreement on Agriculture (AoA)
Protections
and support for agricultural industries began wholeheartedly during the
Great Depression in the 1930s. Not only were tariffs raised along with
most other import products, but a series of price and income support
programs were implemented in many countries. When the first GATT
agreement was negotiated, special exceptions for agriculture were
included, including an allowance to use export subsidies. Recall that
export subsidies are subject to retaliation under the antisubsidy code
but that requirement was negated for agricultural products. This enabled
countries to keep prices for farm products high in the domestic market
and, when those prices generated a surplus of food, to dump that surplus
on international markets by using export subsidies.
The result
of this set of rules implemented worldwide was a severe distortion in
agricultural markets and numerous problems, especially for developing
countries, whose producers would regularly be forced to compete with
low-priced subsidized food for the developed world.
The intention
at the start of the Uruguay Round was a major reduction in tariffs and
quotas and also in domestic support programs. Indeed, in the United
States, the Reagan administration initially proposed a complete
elimination of all trade-distorting subsidies to be phased in over a
ten-year period. What ultimately was achieved was much more modest. The
Uruguay Round agreement missed its deadlines several times because of
the reluctance of some countries, especially the European Community
(EC), to make many concessions to reduce agricultural subsidies.
Countries
did agree to one thing: to make a transition away from quota
restrictions on agricultural commodity imports toward tariffs instead - a
process called tariffication. The logic is that tariffs are more
transparent and would be easier to negotiate downward in future World
Trade Organization (WTO) rounds. A second concession countries made was
to accept at least low levels of market access for important
commodities. For many countries, important food products had prohibitive
quotas in place. A prime example was the complete restriction on rice
imports to Japan. The mechanism used to guarantee these minimum levels
was to implement tariff-rate quotas. A tariff-rate quota sets a low
tariff on a fixed quantity of imports and a high tariff on any imports
over that quota. By setting the quota appropriately and setting a
relatively low tariff on that amount, a country can easily meet its
target minimum import levels.
The General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS)
Trade
in services has become an increasingly important share of international
trade. Trade in transportation, insurance, banking, health, and other
services now accounts for over 20 percent of world trade. However, trade
in services is not restricted by tariffs, largely because services are
not shipped in a container on a ship, truck, or train. Instead, they are
transmitted in four distinct ways. First, they are transmitted by mail,
phone, fax, or the Internet; this is called cross-border supply of
services, or Mode 1. Second, services are delivered when foreign
residents travel to a host country; this is called consumption abroad,
or Mode 2. Third, services trade occurs when a foreign company
establishes a subsidiary abroad; this is called commercial presence, or
Mode 3. Finally, services are delivered when foreign residents travel
abroad to supply them; this is called presence of natural persons, or
Mode 4. Because of the transparent nature of services, economists often
refer to services as "invisibles trade".
Because services are
delivered invisibly, services trade is affected not by tariffs but
rather by domestic regulations. For example, the United States has a law
in place called the Jones Act, which prohibits products being
transported between two U.S. ports on a foreign ship. Consider this
circumstance: a foreign ship arrives at one U.S. port and unloads half
its cargo. It then proceeds to a second U.S. port where it unloads the
remainder. During the trip between ports 1 and 2, the ship is half empty
and the shipping company may be quite eager to sell cargo transport
services to U.S. firms. After all, since the ship is going to port 2
anyway, the marginal cost of additional cargo is almost zero. This would
be an example of Mode 1 services trade, except for the fact that the
Jones Act prohibits this activity even though these services could be
beneficial to both U.S. firms and to the foreign shipping company.
The
Jones Act is only one of innumerable domestic regulations in the United
States that restrict foreign supply of services. Other countries
maintain numerous regulations of their own, restricting access to U.S.
and other service suppliers as well. When the original GATT was
negotiated in the 1940s, services trade was relatively unimportant, and
thus at the time there was no discussion of services regulations
affecting trade. By the time of the Uruguay Round, however, services
trade was increasingly important, and yet there were no provisions to
discuss regulatory changes that could liberalize services trade. The
Uruguay Round changed that.
As a result of Uruguay Round
negotiations, GATT member countries introduced the General Agreement on
Trade in Services, or GATS. The GATS includes a set of specific
commitments countries have made to each other with respect to market
access, market access limitations, and exceptions to national treatment
in specified services. For example, a country may commit to allowing
foreign insurance companies to operate without restrictions.
Alternatively, a country may specify limitations perhaps restricting
foreign insurance company licenses to a fixed number. A country can also
specify a national treatment exception if, say, domestic banks are to
be granted certain privileges that foreign banks are not allowed.
Most
importantly, if exceptions have not been specified, countries have
agreed to maintain most-favored nation (MFN) and national treatment with
respect to services provision. This is an important step in the
direction of trade liberalization largely because a previously uncovered
area of trade that is rapidly growing is now a part of the trade
liberalization effort.
The Agreement on Textiles and Clothing (ATC)
During
the 1950s, 1960s, and 1970s, as tariffs were being negotiated downward,
another type of trade restriction was being used in the textile and
apparel industry: voluntary export restraints. A voluntary export
restraint (VER) is a restriction set by a government on the quantity of
goods that can be exported out of a country during a specified period of
time. Often the word "voluntary" is placed in quotes because these
restraints were often implemented upon the insistence of the importing
nations.
For example, in the mid 1950s, U.S. cotton textile
producers faced increases in Japanese exports of cotton textiles that
negatively affected their profitability. The U.S. government
subsequently negotiated a VER on cotton textiles with Japan. Afterward,
textiles began to flood the U.S. market from other sources like Taiwan
and South Korea. A similar wave of imports affected the nations in
Europe.
The United States and Europe responded by negotiating
VERs on cotton textiles with those countries. By the early 1960s, other
textile producers, who were producing clothing using the new synthetic
fibers like polyester, began to experience the same problem with
Japanese exports that cotton producers faced a few years earlier. So
VERs were negotiated on exports of synthetic fibers, first from Japan
and eventually from many other Southeast Asian nations. These bilateral
VERs continued until eventually exporters and importers of textile
products around the world held a multilateral negotiation resulting in
the Multi-Fiber Agreement (MFA) in 1974. The MFA specified quotas on
exports from all major exporting countries to all major importing
countries. Essentially, it represented a complex arrangement of
multilateral VERs.
The MFA was renewed periodically throughout
the 1970s, 1980s, and 1990s, and it represented a significant setback in
the pursuit of trade liberalization. Thus, as a part of the Uruguay
Round discussions, countries agreed to a significant overhaul of the
MFA. First, the agreement was brought under the control of the WTO and
renamed the Agreement on Textiles and Clothing (ATC). Second, countries
decided to phase out the quotas completely over a ten-year transition
period ending on January 1, 2005.
That transition to a quota-less
industry did occur as scheduled; however, it is worth noting that many
countries continue to maintain higher-than-average tariffs on textile
and apparel products. Therefore, one still cannot say that free trade
has been achieved.
Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS)
One
major expansion of coverage of a trade liberalization agreement was the
inclusion of intellectual property rights (IPR) into the discussion
during the Uruguay Round. IPR covers the protections of written
materials (copyrights), inventions (patents), and brand names and logos
(trademarks). Most countries have established monopoly provisions for
these types of creations to spur the creation of new writing
and inventions and to protect the investments made in the establishment
of trademarks. However, many of these protections have been unequally
enforced worldwide, resulting in a substantial amount of
counterfeiting and pirating. The world is abound in fake CDs and DVDs,
Gucci and Coach purses, and of course the international favorite, Rolex
watches.
To harmonize the IPR protections around the world and to
encourage enforcement of these provisions, countries created an IPR
agreement called the Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property
Rights Agreement, or TRIPS. The TRIPS intends to both encourage trade
and protect writers, inventors, and companies from the theft of their
hard work and investments.
Other Agreements
What is listed and discussed above are just a few of the agreements negotiated during the Uruguay Round. In addition, any round of trade discussions provides an excellent forum for consideration of many other issues that are of particular interest to specific industries. Some of the others include the Agreement on Sanitary and Phytosanitary Measures, which provides guidelines for countries on food safety and plant and animal trade; an agreement on antidumping; the Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures; the Agreement on Trade-Related Investment Measures (TRIMS); the Agreement on Import-Licensing Procedures; the Agreement on Customs Valuation; the Preshipment Inspection Agreement; the Rules of Origin Agreement; and finally, several plurilateral agreements (meaning they don't cover everybody) concerning civilian aircraft, government procurement, and dairy products.
Key Takeaways
- The Uruguay Round of the GATT resulted in numerous new trade-liberalizing agreements among member countries, including the General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS), the Agreement on Agriculture, the Agreement on Textiles and Clothing (ATC), and the Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS), among others.
- The GATS involved commitments to reduce regulations restricting international trade in services.
- The ATC involved commitments to eliminate the quota system established in the 1970s on textile and apparel products.
- The Agreement on Agriculture involved some modest commitments to reduce support for the agricultural industry.
- The TRIPS agreement involved commitments to standardize the treatment and enforcement of intellectual property rights.
The World Trade Organization
In
order to monitor and sustain the complete set of Uruguay Round
agreements, the member countries established a new body called the World
Trade Organization (WTO). The WTO is a relatively small organization
based in Geneva, Switzerland. It has a director-general, currently
Pascal Lamy (as of January 2010), and a small staff of economists,
lawyers, and others. The goal of the WTO is the same goal as its
predecessor, the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT): namely,
to promote trade liberalization and thereby to foster growth and
economic development.
Sometimes the WTO is described as an
international organization governing international trade. However, this
description can be misleading. The WTO does not make trade rules. The
only makers of rules are national governments. In this sense, then, the
WTO does not govern anybody. A better way to think of the WTO is as a
club of member nations. The club's purpose is to monitor each member
country's trade policies with respect to the trade agreements that were
made in the Uruguay Round. The WTO agreements include thousands of
promises for every country, all intending to reduce barriers to trade
relative to what the barriers were before the Uruguay Round. The WTO
does not represent free trade. At best, the agreements can be described
as freer trade.
Besides monitoring each member country's trade
policies, which the WTO fulfills by conducting periodic trade policy
reviews of the member countries, the WTO club was also created to deal
with disputes. This is surely the most important "power" of the WTO.
The Dispute Settlement Process
Disputes
are handled by the Dispute Settlement Body (DSB). The DSB works like a
committee that meets regularly to discuss any issues countries may have
with respect to each other's trade policies. The DSB is comprised of one
representative from each member country. When they meet, countries have
the right to object to the trade policies of another country. However,
they cannot object to anything or everything; instead, a country can
only object to an unfulfilled promise with respect to one or more of the
WTO agreements.
When the Uruguay Round was finalized, each
member country went back to its own legislature and changed its trade
policies and rules to conform to its new commitments. Sometimes
inadvertently and sometimes purposely, some countries do not implement
their commitments fully. Or sometimes a country believes that it has
fulfilled its commitment, but its trading partner believes otherwise. Or
new legislation may violate one of the country's previous commitments.
In these cases, a member country (the complainant) is allowed to
register a dispute with the DSB against another member country (the
defendant). Resolution of a dispute follows these steps:
-
Consultations. The DSB first demands that the appropriate government
representatives from the complainant country and the defendant country
meet to discuss the dispute. They must do this within a strict timetable
(less than sixty days) and hopefully will be able to resolve the
dispute without external intervention.
- Panel formation. If the
countries return to the DSB at a later session and report that the
consultations failed, then the complainant may ask the DSB to form a
panel. A panel consists of three to five independent trade law experts
who are hired expressly to make a judgment about the particular dispute.
The DSB chooses the panelists in consultation with the disputing
countries, or the panelists are chosen by the director-general if the
countries cannot agree. The panel is generally given about six months to
decide whether the defendant violated some of its promises, whereupon
it reports its decision to the DSB. Since a panel report can only be
rejected by consensus, no country has veto power over DSB adoption of a
report. Thus all panel reports become official decisions. But the
process does not yet end.
- Appeals. Either country can appeal the
decision given in the panel report. A request or appeal sends the issue
to an appellate board comprised of three judges drawn from a set of
seven, each of whom has a four-year term. As in the U.S. court system,
appellate arguments must be based on points of law relating to legal
interpretations but cannot consider new evidence or retry the case. As
with the original panel reports, appellate decisions are almost
automatically adopted by the DSB.
- Resolution. If the
appellate board concurs with a panel decision that a defendant country
has violated some of its WTO agreement commitments, there are two paths
to resolution:
- Compliance. In the preferred outcome, the
defendant country complies with the ruling against it and changes its
laws as needed to conform. Sometimes compliance may take time because of
delays in a legislative process, so normally the defendant will be
given time to rectify the situation. In the process, the country will be
expected to report its progress regularly to the DSB.
- Suspension of concessions. Sometimes a country refuses to comply with a ruling or it takes longer than the complainant is willing to wait. In this case, the complainant country is allowed by the DSB to suspend some of its previous concessions toward the defendant country. It works like this: Since it has been shown that the defendant has not lived up to all of its previous promises, the complainant is now allowed to rescind some of its own trade-liberalizing promises, but only toward the defendant country. To be fair, the rescission must affect the defendant that is approximately equal in value to the cost imposed by the defendant's violations.
- Compliance. In the preferred outcome, the
defendant country complies with the ruling against it and changes its
laws as needed to conform. Sometimes compliance may take time because of
delays in a legislative process, so normally the defendant will be
given time to rectify the situation. In the process, the country will be
expected to report its progress regularly to the DSB.
Dispute Settlement History
Since
the WTO began in 1995 there have been over four hundred disputes
brought to the DSB. Many countries have been complainants and defendants although
the two countries most often on one side or the other are the United
States and the EU. Some of the most well-known disputes have involved
bananas, steel, hormone-treated beef, and commercial aircraft.
Lesser-known cases have involved narrow product groups such as Circular
Welded Carbon Quality Line Pipe, Canned Tuna with Soybean Oil, Combed
Cotton Yarn, and Retreaded Tires.
Many cases have been raised
once, sent to consultations, and then never raised again. In some cases,
consultations are sufficient to settle the dispute. Many other cases
proceed to panel formation, appeals, and resolution. In many cases,
defendants lose and eventually change their laws to comply with the WTO
decision. In other cases, defendants lose and because of their refusal
to comply, or their procrastination in complying, complainants suspend
concessions. In a few cases, countries have refused to comply and faced
no consequences. Occasionally, a defendant wins its case against a
complainant.
Overall, the WTO dispute process has worked
reasonably well. The cases brought, because they are often targeted to
narrow industries, do not affect a huge amount of international trade.
Nonetheless the existence of a forum in which to register disputes and a
mechanism for resolving them (one that includes some penalties for
violations) has had a notable effect of reducing the risk of
international trade.
Traders know better what to expect from
their trading partners because their partners have committed themselves
to particular trade policies and to a resolution mechanism in the event
of noncompliance. In a sense, then, it is true that the WTO agreements
restrict the freedom of a country to set whatever trade policy it deems
appropriate for the moment. That loss of sovereignty, though, is
designed to prevent countries from choosing more destructive
protectionist policies - policies that are very seductive to voters,
especially in an economic crisis. If successful, the WTO could prevent a
reoccurrence of Smoot-Hawley and its aftermath both now and in the
future.
Key Takeaways
- The WTO's main purpose is to monitor the trade liberalization agreements reached by GATT member countries in the Uruguay Round.
- The most important "power" of the WTO is its ability to adjudicate disputes between member countries regarding compliance with the Agreements.
- Dispute resolution is conducted by the Dispute Settlement Body (DSB), which includes one representative from each WTO government.
- The four main steps to a WTO dispute case are (1) consultations, (2) panel formation, (3) appeals, and (4) resolution.
Appendix A: Selected U.S. Tariffs – 2009
Table 1.2 "Special
Tariff Classifications in the United States" contains a selection of the
U.S. tariff rates specified in the 2009 U.S. Harmonized Tariff Schedule
(HTS). The complete U.S. HTS is available at the U.S. International
Trade Commission Web site (http://www.usitc.gov).
Symbol | Description |
---|---|
A, A∗, A+ | Generalized System of Preferences (GSP) |
AU | U.S.-Australia free trade area (FTA) |
B | Automotive Products Trade Act |
BH | U.S.-Bahrain FTA |
C | Agreement on Civil Aircraft |
CA, MX | North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA): Canada and Mexico |
CL | U.S.-Chile FTA |
D | African Growth and Opportunity Act (AGOA) |
E | Caribbean Basin Economic Recovery Act |
IL | U.S.-Israel FTA |
J, J∗, J+ | Andean Trade Preference Act |
JO | U.S.-Jordan FTA |
K | Agreement on Pharmaceuticals |
P, P+ | CAFTA-DR FTA |
PE | U.S.-Peru FTA |
MA | U.S.-Morocco FTA |
OM | U.S.-Oman FTA |
R | U.S.-Caribbean Trade Partnership Act |
SG | U.S.-Singapore FTA |
Table 1.2 Special Tariff Classifications in the United States
The
tariff schedule in Table 1.3 "Selected Tariffs in the United States,
2009" displays four columns. The first column gives a brief description
of the product. The second column shows the product classification
number. The first two numbers refer to the chapter, the most general
product specification. For example, 08 refers to chapter 8, "Edible
fruit and nuts; peel of citrus fruit or melons." The product
classification becomes more specific for each digit to the right. Thus
0805 refers more specifically to "Citrus fruit, fresh or dried." The
code 0805 40 refers to "Grapefruit," and 0805 40 40 refers to
"Grapefruit entering between August 1 and September 30." This
classification system is harmonized among about two hundred countries up
to the first six digits and is overseen by the World Customs
Organization.
The third column displays the "General Rate of
Duty" for that particular product. This is the tariff that the United
States applies to all countries with most-favored nation (MFN) status,
or as it is now referred to in the United States, "normal trade
relations" (NTR). The status was renamed NTR to provide a more accurate
description of the term. One provision in the U.S. GATT/WTO agreements
is that the United States promises to provide every WTO member country
with MFN status. As a matter of policy, the United States also typically
grants most non-WTO countries the same status. For example, as of 2009,
Russia was not a member of the WTO, but the United States applied its
NTR tariff rates to Russian imports.
The final column lists
special rates of duty that apply to select countries under special
circumstances. For each product, you will see a tariff rate followed by a
list of symbols in parentheses. The symbols indicate the trade act or
free trade agreement that provides special tariff treatment to those
countries. A complete list of these is shown in Table 1.2 "Special
Tariff Classifications in the United States." Symbols that include a "+"
or "∗" generally refer to special exceptions that apply for some
countries with that product.
In the standard U.S. tariff
schedule, there is one additional column labeled "2." This is the U.S.
non-MFN tariff, meaning essentially the nonspecial tariffs. Many of
these tariff rates, especially for product categories that have been
around for a long time, are holdovers from the Smoot-Hawley tariffs set
in the Tariff Act of 1930. They are significantly higher than the
standard MFN tariffs in column 1 but apply to only two countries: Cuba
and North Korea.
Description | HTS Code | MFN/NTR Tariff | Special Tariff |
---|---|---|---|
Cauliflower, broccoli | 0704.10.20 | 2.5% (June 5–Oct. 25) | Free (A,AU,BH,CA,CL,E,IL,J,JO,MA,MX,OM,P,PE,SG) |
0704.10.40 | 10% (Other, not reduced in size) | Free (A,AU,BH,CA,CL,E,IL,J,JO,MA,MX,OM,P,PE,SG) | |
0704.10.60 | 14% (Cut or sliced) |
Free (A,BH,CA,CL,E,IL,J,JO,MA,MX,OM,P,PE) 7% (AU) 3.5% (SG) |
|
Grapefruit, incl. pomelos | 0805.40.40 | 1.9¢/kg (Aug.–Sept.) | Free (AU,BH,CA,D,E,IL,J,JO,MA,MX,OM,P,PE,SG) |
0805.40.60 | 1.5¢/kg (Oct.) |
Free (CA, CL, D, E,IL,J,JO,MX,P,PE, SG) 1¢/kg (AU) 0.9¢/kg (BH) 1.1¢/kg (MA) 1.2¢/kg (OM) |
|
0805.40.80 | 2.5¢/kg (Nov.–July) |
Free (CA, D, E, IL, J, JO, MX, P, PE) 1.8¢/kg (AU,MA) 1.5¢/kg (BH) 1¢/kg (CL,SG) 2.2¢/kg (OM) |
|
Grapes, fresh | 0806.10.20 | $1.13/m3 (Feb. 15–Mar. 31) | Free (A+,AU,BH,CA,CL,D,E,IL,J,JO,MA,MX,OM,P,PE,SG) |
0806.10.40 | Free (Apr. 1–June 30) | ||
0806.10.60 | $1.80/m3 (any other time) | Free (A+,AU,BH,CA,CL,D,E,IL,J,JO,MA,MX,OM,P,PE,SG) | |
Ceramic tableware; cups valued over $5.25 per dozen; saucers valued over $3 per dozen; soups, oatmeals, and cereals valued over $6 per dozen; plates not over 22.9 cm in maximum diameter and valued over $6 per dozen; plates over 22.9 but not over 27.9 cm in maximum diameter and valued over $8.50 per dozen; platters or chop dishes valued over $35 per dozen; sugars valued over $21 per dozen; creamers valued over $15 per dozen; and beverage servers valued over $42 per dozen | 6912.00.45 | 4.5% |
Free (A+,AU,CA,CL,D,E,IL,J, JO,MX,P,PE,SG) 2.7% (BH) 2.4% (MA) 4% (OM) |
Motor cars principally designed for the transport of persons, of all cylinder capacities | 8703.2x.00 | 2.5% | Free (A+,AU,B,BH,CA,CL,D,E,IL,J,JO,MA,MX,OM,P,PE,SG) |
Motor vehicles for the transport of goods (i.e., trucks), gross vehicle weight exceeding 5 metric tons but less than 20 metric tons | 8704.22.50 | 25% |
Free (A+,AU,B,BH,CA,CL,D,E,IL,J,MA,MX,OM,P,PE) 2.5% (JO) 10% (SG) |
Bicycles having both wheels not exceeding 63.5 cm in diameter | 8712.00.15 | 11% |
Free (A+,AU,BH,CA,CL,D,E,IL,J,JO,MA,MX,OM,P,PE) 1.3% (SG) |
Cane sugar | 1701.11.05 | 1.4606¢/kg less 0.020668¢/kg for each degree under 100 degrees but not less than 0.943854¢/kg | Free (A∗,AU,BH,CA,CL,E∗,IL,J,JO,MA,MX,OM,P,PE,SG) |
Sports footwear: tennis shoes, basketball shoes, gym shoes, training shoes and the like: having uppers of which over 50% of the external surface area is leather | 6404.11.20 | 10.5% |
Free (AU,BH,CA,CL,D,E,IL,J+,JO,MA,MX,OM,P,PE,R) 1.3% (SG) |
Golf clubs | 9506.31.00 | 4.4% | Free (A,AU,BH,CA,CL,E,IL,J,JO,MA,MX,OM,P,PE,SG) |
Wristwatches | 9101.11.40 | 51¢ each + 6.25% on case and strap + 5.3% on battery | Free (AU,BH,CA,CL,D,E,IL,J,J+,JO,MA,MX,OM,P,PE,R,SG) |
Fax machines | 8517.21.00 | Free | |
Coffee, caffeinated | 0901.21.00 | Free | |
Tea, green tea, flavored | 0902.10.10 | 6.4% | Free (A,AU,BH,CA,CL,E,IL,J,JO,MA,MX,OM,P,PE,SG) |
Table 1.3 Selected Tariffs in the United States, 2009
The
products presented in Table 1.3 "Selected Tariffs in the United States,
2009" were selected to demonstrate several noteworthy features of U.S.
trade policy. The WTO reports in the 2006 U.S. trade policy review that
most goods enter the United States either duty free or with very low
tariffs. Coffee and fax machines are two goods, shown above,
representative of the many goods that enter duty free. The average MFN
tariff in the United States in 2002 was about 5 percent, although for
agricultural goods the rate was almost twice as high. About 7 percent of
U.S. tariffs exceed 15 percent; these are mostly sensitive products
such as peanuts, dairy, footwear, textiles, and clothing. The
trade-weighted average tariff in the United States was only about 1.5
percent in 2003.
One interesting feature of the tariff schedule
is the degree of specificity of the products in the HTS schedule.
Besides product type, categories are divided according to weight, size,
or the time of year. Note especially the description of ceramic
tableware and bicycles.
Tariffs vary according to time of entry,
as with cauliflower, grapefruit, and grapes. This reflects the harvest
season for those products in the United States. When the tariff is low,
that product is out of season in the United States. Higher tariffs are
in place when U.S. output in the product rises.
Notice the
tariffs on cauliflower and broccoli. They are lower if the vegetables
are unprocessed. If the product is cut or sliced before arriving in the
United States, the tariff rises to 14 percent. This reflects a case of
tariff escalation. Tariff escalation means charging a higher tariff the
greater the degree of processing for a product. This is a common
practice among many developed countries and serves to protect domestic
processing industries. Developing countries complain that these
practices impede their development by preventing them from competing in
more advanced industries. Consequently, tariff escalation is a common
topic of discussion during trade liberalization talks.
Tariff
rates also vary with different components of the same product, as with
watches. Note also that watches have both specific tariffs and ad
valorem tariffs applied.
Notice that the tariff on cars in the
United States is 2.5 percent, but the tariff on truck imports is ten
times that rate at 25 percent. The truck tariff dates back to 1963 and
is sometimes called the "chicken tax." It was implemented
primarily to affect Volkswagen in retaliation for West Germany's high
tariff on chicken imports from the United States. Today, Canada and
Mexico are exempt from the tariff due to NAFTA, and Australia will also
be exempt with the new U.S.-Australia FTA. The truck tax is set to be a
contentious issue in current U.S.-Thailand FTA discussions.
The
tariff rates themselves are typically set to several significant digits.
One has to wonder why the United States charges 4.4 percent on golf
clubs rather than an even 4 percent or 5 percent. Much worse is the
tariff rate on cane sugar with six significant digits.
The
special tariff rates are often labeled "free," meaning these goods enter
duty-free from that group of countries. Note that Chile and Singapore
sometimes have tariff rates in between the MFN rate and zero. This
reflects the FTA's phase in the process. Most FTAs include a five- to
fifteen-year phase-in period during which time tariffs are reduced
annually toward zero.
One thing to think about while reviewing
this tariff schedule is the administrative cost of monitoring and taxing
imported goods. Not only does the customs service incur costs to
properly categorize and measure goods entering the country, but foreign
firms themselves must be attuned to the intricacies of the tariff
schedule of all the countries to which they export. All of this requires
the attention and time of employees of the firms and represents a cost
of doing business. These administrative costs are rarely included in the
evaluation of trade policies.
An administratively cheaper
alternative would be to charge a fixed ad valorem tariff on all goods
that enter, much like a local sales tax. However, for political reasons,
it would be almost impossible to switch to this much simpler
alternative.
Appendix B: Bound versus Applied Tariffs
The WTO agreement
includes commitments by countries to bind their tariff rates at an
agreed-upon maximum rate for each import product category. The maximum
tariff in a product category is called the bound tariff rate. The bound
tariff rates differ across products and countries: some agree to higher maximums, others agree to lower maximums. In general,
less-developed countries have higher bound tariff rates than developed
countries, reflecting their perception that they need greater protection
from competition against the more highly developed industries in the
developed markets.
However, some countries, especially those with
higher bound tariffs, set their actual tariffs at lower
levels than their bound rates. The actual tariff rate is called the
applied tariff rate. Table 1.4, "Bound versus Applied Average Tariffs,"
lists the average applied tariff rates compared to average bound tariffs
for a selected set of WTO member countries. The averages are calculated
as a simple average: namely, the ad valorem tariff rates (bound or
applied) are added together and divided by the total number of tariff
categories. These are not trade-weighted average tariffs.
Also, when
specific tariffs are assessed for a product, they are excluded from the
calculations. (Note that specific tariffs are set as a dollar charge per
unit of imports.) Also listed is the percentage of six-digit tariff
lines with a tariff binding. For products that have no tariff
binding, the country is free to set whatever tariff it wishes. The
countries are ordered from the highest to the lowest gross domestic
product (GDP) per person.
Country | Applied Rate (%) | Bound Rate (%) | % Bound |
---|---|---|---|
United States | 3.6 | 3.6 | 100.0 |
Canada | 3.6 | 5.1 | 99.7 |
EC | 4.3 | 4.1 | 100.0 |
Japan | 3.1 | 2.9 | 99.6 |
South Korea | 11.3 | 16.0 | 94.7 |
Mexico | 12.5 | 34.9 | 100.0 |
Chile | 6.0 (uniform) | 25.1 | 100.0 |
Argentina | 11.2 | 32.0 | 100.0 |
Brazil | 13.6 | 31.4 | 100.0 |
Thailand | 9.1 | 25.7 | 74.7 |
China | 9.95 | 10.0 | 100.0 |
Egypt | 17.0 | 36.8 | 99.3 |
Philippines | 6.3 | 25.6 | 66.8 |
India | 15.0 | 49.7 | 73.8 |
Kenya | 12.7 | 95.7 | 14.6 |
Ghana | 13.1 | 92.5 | 14.3 |
Table 1.4 Bound versus Applied Average Tariffs
- More-developed countries apply lower average tariffs than less-developed countries (LDCs).
- Average bound tariff rates are higher for less-developed countries. This means the WTO agreement has not forced LDCs to open their economies to the same degree as developed countries.
- The less developed a country, the fewer tariff categories that are bound. For the most developed economies, 100 percent of the tariff lines are bound, but for Ghana and Kenya, only 14 percent are bound. This also means that the WTO agreement has not forced LDCs to open their economies to the same degree as developed countries.
- For LDCs, applied tariffs are set much lower on average than the bound rates. These countries can raise their tariffs without violating their WTO commitments.
- China has lower tariffs and greater bindings than countries of similar wealth.
- Since the most developed economies have applied rates equal to bound rates, they cannot raise tariffs without violating their WTO commitments. WTO-sanctioned trade remedy actions can be used instead, however.